• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Economics Letters:Vol70.Issue1.Jan2001:

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Economics Letters:Vol70.Issue1.Jan2001:"

Copied!
7
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

www.elsevier.com / locate / econbase

Linear-homothetic preferences

*

Bipasa Datta, Huw Dixon

Department of Economics& Related Studies, University of York, Heslington, York YO10 5DD, UK Received 1 January 2000; accepted 25 April 2000

Abstract

This paper develops a new class of linear homothetic (LH ) preferences that result in Marshallian demands that are linear in price under the assumption that agents take aggregate price indeces as given (as in monopolistic competition). The preferences are represented by a cost-function that has one parameter, which can be interpreted as the elasticity of demand when all prices are equal. The cost-function has a restricted form that

allows the elasticity of demand to be compatible with any number of commodities.  2000 Elsevier Science

S.A. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Duality; Homothetic; Linear

JEL classification: D1; D2

1. Introduction

This paper introduces a new class of homothetic preferences which have the useful property that the demand for each commodity is in an important sense linear in own price. Linear Homothetic (LH ) preferences will be useful in general equilibrium settings, particularly with wage or price-setting agents. Linearity is a very useful property for demand curves: it has been very extensively analyzed in the partial equilibrium setting in a variety of contexts (for example union-firm bargaining, industrial organization) where it is the reference point for many modelling exercises. In a general equilibrium

1

context, however, linearity of demand is presently modelled with quadratic preferences . The use of quadratic preferences has properties that may be undesirable in some contexts: in particular, there is a satiation point. Homotheticity is also widely used in applied general equilibrium models, including

*Corresponding author. Tel.: 144-1904-433-788; fax: 144-1904-433-759. E-mail address: hddl@york.ac.uk (H. Dixon).

1

For example, by specifying preferences for two goods x and y as quasi-linear x1u( y), with the further assumption that

2

u( y)5y2y .

(2)

trade theory, macroeconomics and CGE. The two most commonly used homothetic preferences are CES and Cobb–Douglas (CD ). Whilst appropriate in some applications, they have special properties that may be undesirable in others: for example, CES and CD give rise to non-monotonic reaction

2

functions in Cournot oligopoly which can make asymmetric equilibria difficult to analyze .

The approach we adopt is to specify a particular functional form for the cost function, which has one parameter — the elasticity of demand when prices are equal. Under the assumption of Aggregate Price Taking (APT ), as in the Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) model of monopolistic competition, this results in a linear Marshallian demand curve. The cost function is constructed in such a way that preferences are homothetic. We develop a restricted version of our cost-function that allows for any combination of equilibrium elasticity and number of industries / goods while simultaneously satisfying all the required properties.

2. The LH cost function

There are n products, i51 . . . n, the n-vector of prices p is p. The expenditure function takes thei n

homothetic form E(p, u)5b(p).u where b: R1→R1 is the unit cost of utility. b is a unit cost

3

function if it satisfies the following properties : (i) b is non-negative and non-decreasing in prices; (ii)

4

b is homogenous of degree 1 and concave in p; (iii) b is continuously differentiable . Consider the function b

The function b clearly satisfies properties (ii) and (iii) for any p[R1: however, property (i) need n

not be satisfied for all p[R . Denoting db / dp by b , Proposition 1 gives a necessary and sufficient

1 i i

for property (i) to hold for all prices.

n Hence a necessary and sufficient condition for b$0 for all prices is

2

See for example Santoni (1996) for an application of union-firm bargaining in an oligopoly with Cobb–Douglas preferences.

3

For a fuller listing of necessary and sufficient conditions, see (Diewert, 1982, pp. 537–547).

4

Continuous differentiability is not required for b to be a cost-function: however this enables us to apply Shephard’s lemma.

5

(3)

1 g

]Œ]n$]]11g (3)

A necessary and sufficient condition for bi$0 is (11g) /g$p /pi . The maximum value of p /i p is

] Œ

achieved when all prices j±i are zero, i.e. max p /p5 n. Hence a necessary and sufficient i

condition for bi$0 for all prices is

11g

]

Œn#]]g (4)

Both (3), (4) are equivalent to (2). This is a sufficient condition for b$0 and bi$0: it is necessary n

since these properties are to hold for all prices p[R1. h

When g50, condition (2) is satisfied for all prices: b then represents Leontief preferences. We derive below a more general form of the cost function which we call the restricted LH cost function which ensures that the non-negativity conditions are satisfied for all g and n. First, however, we assume that (2) is satisfied, so that the budget sharesai corresponding to (1) are given by Shephard’s lemma:

p xi i pi

]]Y 5]bbi;ai(p) (5)

where Y is total expenditure on all commodities yielding the Marshallian demand

pi Y

] ]

F

G

xi5 (11g)2gp nb (6)

This is non-linear, sincep is non-linear. However, we assume in the spirit of the Dixit–Stiglitz (D –S ) model of monopolistic competition (Dixit and Stiglitz, 1977) that there is Aggregate price taking

6

(APT ): The aggregate price indices p and b are treated as parameters by individual agents . Under the assumption of Aggregate Price Taking (APT), (6) is perceived linear in p . Note that the lineari demand has a choke-off price: xi$0 only when p /i p#(11g) /g. This is exactly the same as the condition for non-negative own price derivatives as stated in Proposition 1, since the quantities are derived using Shephard’s Lemma. Treatingp and b as given, the own price elasticity of demand (in absolute value) is parameter g is the elasticity of demand in any symmetric equilibrium. Note that the elasticity of demand is an increasing function of p if we treati p as constant.

6

(4)

3. The restricted LH cost function

The previous analysis has been made under the assumption that given n the elasticity of demand satisfies condition (2). In the case of price-making agents (e.g. monopolistic firms) it is often

7

necessary to assume that the industry demand is elastic: in this case (2) is overly restrictive . We restrict the cost function b in such a way that the properties (particularly property (i)) of a cost

n

function are satisfied for anyg and n. First, let us define the subset of R where b $0 given g

1 i

budget shares are non-negative. This is achieved by sequentially lowering prices starting with the n11 n highest until there are no non-negative budget shares using a price-capping function g: R1 →R1,

ˆ which places a cap (upper bound) of l on prices, yielding the n-vector of capped prices p

ˆ

p5g(l, p)5(min[l, p ])i i51 . . . n

Clearly, g is homogeneous of degree 1 and continuous in (p, l). However, g is not continuously

9 generality, we will assume that the price vector is ordered in terms of uncapped price, p1#

max

which gives the largest value of l such that the capped price vector is in b(g, n), i.e.

l(p)5 maxmax l

p $l$0 (8)

s.t. b ( g(li , p))$0 i51 . . . n

By the theorem of the maximum, l(p) is continuous in p (since b and g are continuous andi l is

max

(5)

10 max Lemma. Derivatives of l(p) : (i ) l 50 if p .l; (ii ) 1.l .0 if p ,l and l,p ; (iii )

i i i i

max max

li50 if pi,p and l5p .

Proof. First consider (i) and (ii) where price capping is operative. With capping binding at p , we havej

ˆ

We can now define the restricted LH cost function B(p)

B(p)5b( g(l(p), p)) (10)

Proposition 2. Properties of restricted LH cost function B(p).

(i ) B is continuous and homogeneous of degree 1 in p (ii ) B is continuous in p, with B (p)i i 5b ( g(i l, p)) (iii ) B is concave in p

(6)

max max

However, from the definition ofl(p), if p .pj$l then bj50; if p 5l then li50. Hence

11

the RHS summation is zero (since li bounded) . Since b is continuous ini l and p, and l is continuous in p, the result follows.

(iii) Concavity of b implies that for any p, p9

9

b(p)#b(p9)1

O

b (p)( pi i2p )i (a)

i51 . . . n

Now suppose that B(p) is not concave. Then there exists some p, p9 such that

9

B(p).B(p9)1

O

B (p)( pi i2p )i

i51 . . . n

ˆ ˆ

From the definition of B and (ii) we have for p5g(l(p), p) and p9 5g(l(p9), p9)

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

9

b(p ).b(p9)1

O

b (pi 9)(pi2p )i

i51 . . . n

But this contradicts (a). Hence B is concave in p. h

The restricted LH cost-function B allows any combination of (g, n) while simultaneously satisfying all the desired properties of a cost function. However, in practice, it will be possible to use the simple

] 21

Œ

cost-function b even wheng .s n21d . This is because in many applications, the actual prices set in a particular model will be ones resulting in positive outputs, where the price-cap in the restricted cost function is non-binding: e.g. monopolists will usually set prices which result in strictly positive outputs. However, Proposition 2 allows use to use b with confidence.

4. Conclusion

In this paper we have developed a new class of preferences that combines the desirable properties of homotheticity with (perceived) linearity. The class of preferences is parameterized by the elasticity of the Marshallian demand. We are able to develop this idea using the dual approach of the cost function. We believe that LH preferences will be useful in a variety of applications. Most importantly, in models where there is a within industry asymmetry in oligopoly: for example, where one firm moves first and / or firms have different cost structures.

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Karim Abadir, Gianni de Fraja, Gaia Garino, Michele Santoni and Peter Simmons for helpful comments and encouragement. Faults remain our own.

11

(7)

References

Diewert, W.E., 1982. In: Arrow, K.J., Intrilligator, M. (Eds.), Duality Approaches to Microeconomic Theory, Handbook of Mathematical Economics. NHPC, pp. 535–600.

Dixit, A., Stiglitz, J., 1977. Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review 67, 297–308.

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

20 Urusan Wajib Otonomi Daerah, Pemerintahan Umum, Adm KeuDa, Perangkat Daerah, Kepegawaian. Organisasi

Formulir RKAP SKPD RINGKASAN RENCANA KERJA ANGGARAN PERUBAHAN.. SATUAN KERJA

Dengan ini kami beritahukan bahwa perusahaan saudara adalah sebagai Calon Pemenang untuk pekerjaan Pengawasan Teknis Irigasi Tahun 2015 , maka kami mengundang

[r]

Untuk mengetahui apakah usaha ternak sapi di PT.Sulung Ranch layak atau tidak dapat dihitung dengan analisis kelayakan finansial dari biaya investasi dan biaya operasional yang

Paket pengadaan ini terbuka untuk penyedia barang/jasa yang teregistrasi pada Layanan Pengadaan Secara Elektronik (LPSE) dan memiliki Surat Izin Usaha Jasa Konstruksi

PEMERINTAH KOTA BANJARBARU UNIT LAYANAN PENGADAAN..

setelah dilaksanakan Evaluasi Ulang Dokumen Penawaran dan Dokumen Kualifikasi terhadap penawaran-penawaran yang masuk untuk paket pekerjaan tersebut diatas