• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

3.6 Extensions

3.6.4 Partially Asymmetric Information

In this modification of the main text version of the private vetting model, the politician observes σ, which contains both the public knowledge in the vetting agency’s report about her policy and her own knowledge of her competence. However, the voter only observes the public vetting about the politician, which indicates the expected probability that she is competent, πτ. Whenever πτ > π0τ, I assume that the distribution of σ givenπτ strictly first order stochastically dominates (FOSDs) the distribution givenπτ0 on[0,1]. I also add the assumption thatσpri is unique, as the proof of uniqueness used in the main text requires that the expectedσ be equal to 12. All of the other assumptions are maintained from Section 3.3.

Asπτ increases, the voter expects the politician to have better signals, and consequently the expected signal for any given cutoff is higher.

Lemma 3.8. If πτ > π0τ,ER(στ)> ER(στ0).

Proof. Let the distribution for σ given πτ beg and the distribution givenπ0τ be h. By assumption, g strictly FOSDsh on [0,1]. Using the definition ofER, it must be shown that

Rσ

0 σdG(σ) +γR1

σσdG(σ)

>

Rσ

0 σdH(σ) +γR1

σσdH(σ)

. (3.93)

First order stochastic dominance implies that Z σ

0

σdG(σ)>

Z σ 0

σdH(σ) (3.94)

and

Z 1 σ

σdG(σ)>

Z 1 σ

σdH(σ). (3.95)

Consequently, the numerator of the left hand side of (3.93) must be larger than the numerator of the right hand side. Further, G(σ) < H(σ) for any σ by first order stochastic dominance. Hence, the denominator of the left hand side of (3.93) must be smaller than that of the right hand side as well.

Recall that σpri solves F−1pri) = ER(σpri). Hence, when ER(σpri) increases because of an increase in πτ, F−1pri) must also increase. Consequently, because F−1(σ) is strictly increasing, the value of σpri must be greater for πτ than forπ0τ. Hence, as πτ increases, the value of σpri increases. When the politician has a higherπτ, she implements the policy only for larger realizations of σ. Because σ is the probability of success, the politician is effectively becoming more risk averse asπτ increases, as a strictly higher probability is required for the lottery of policy implementation to be acceptable to her.

References

Alonso, Ricardo, and Odilon Câmara. 2016. “Political disagreement and information in elections.” Games and Economic Behavior 100:390–412.

Aragonès, Enriqueta, and Thomas R Palfrey. 2002. “Mixed equilibrium in a Downsian model with a favored candidate.”Journal of Economic Theory 103:131–161.

Aragonès, Enriqueta, and Dimitrios Xefteris. 2012. “Candidate quality in a Downsian model with a continuous policy space.”Games and Economic Behavior 75:464–480.

Asay, Garrett R Beeler. 2008. “How does ideology matter in the spatial model of voting?” Public Choice 135:109–123.

Austen-Smith, David, and Jeffrey S. Banks. 1996. “Information aggregation, rationality, and the Condorcet Jury Theorem.”American Political Science Review 90:34–45.

Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Michael C. Herron, and Kenneth W. Shotts. 2001. “Leadership and Pandering: A Theory of Executive Policymaking.”American Journal of Political Science45:532–550.

Chung, Hun, and John Duggan. 2018. “Directional Equilibria.”Journal of Theoretical Politics 30:272–305.

Cohen, Linda. 1979. “Cyclic sets in multidimensional voting models.”Journal of Economic Theory 20:1–12.

Cohen, Linda, and Steven Matthews. 1980. “Constrained Plott equilibria, directional equilibria and global cycling sets.”Review of Economic Studies 47:975–986.

Dewan, Torun, and Rafael Hortala-Vallve. 2017. “Electoral Competition, Control and Learning.”British Journal of Political Science:1–17.

Downs, Anthony. 1957. “An economic theory of political action in a democracy.”Journal of Political Economy 65:135–150.

Duggan, John. 2018. “Necessary gradient restrictions at the core of a voting rule.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 79:1–9.

Dziubiński, Marcin, and Jaideep Roy. 2011. “Electoral competition in 2-dimensional ideology space with uni- dimensional commitment.”Social Choice and Welfare36:1–24.

Fox, Justin, and Matthew C. Stephenson. 2011. “Judicial Review as a Response to Political Posturing.”American Political Science Review 105 (2): 397–414.

Fox, Justin, and Richard Van Weelden. 2015. “Hoping for the best, unprepared for the worst.”Journal of Public Economics 130:59–65.

Fu, Qiang, and Ming Li. 2014. “Reputation-concerned policy makers and institutional status quo bias.”Journal of Public Economics110:15–25.

Gratton, Gabriele. 2014. “Pandering and electoral competition.” Games and Economic Behavior 84:163–179.

Groseclose, Tim. 2001. “A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage.”American Journal of Political Science 45:862–886.

. 2007. “‘One and a half dimensional preferences and majority rule.”Social Choice and Welfare 28:321–

335.

Heidhues, Paul, and Johan Lagerlöf. 2003. “Hiding information in electoral competition.”Games and Economic Behavior 42:48–74.

Holmström, Bengt. 1999. “Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective.”Review of Economic Studies 66 (January): 169–182.

Hotelling, Harold. 1929. “Stability in Competition.”Economic Journal 39:41–57.

Hummel, Patrick. 2010. “On the nature of equilibria in a Downsian model with candidate valence.”Games and Economic Behavior 70:425–445.

Izzo, Federica. 2019. “With friends like these, who needs enemies?” Accessed March 6, 2020. https://www.

federicaizzo.com/research.php.

Jensen, Thomas. 2015. “Elections, information, and state-dependent candidate quality.”Journal of Public Eco- nomic Theory 17:702–723.

Kartik, Navin, Francesco Squintani, and Katrin Tinn. 2015. “Information revelation and pandering in elections.”

Accessed March 6, 2020.http://www.columbia.edu/~nk2339/.

Krasa, Stefan, and Mattias Polborn. 2010. “The binary policy model.” Journal of Economic Theory 145:661–

688.

. 2014. “Social ideology and taxes in a differentiated candidates framework.”American Economic Review 104:308–22.

Krasa, Stefan, and Mattias K Polborn. 2012. “Political competition between differentiated candidates.”Games and Economic Behavior 76:249–271.

Majumdar, Sumon, and Sharun W. Mukand. 2004. “Policy Gambles.”American Economic Review 94 (Septem- ber): 1207–1222.

Martin, Mathieu, Zéphirin Nganmeni, and Craig A Tovey. 2016. “On the uniqueness of the yolk.”Social Choice and Welfare47:511–518.

Matakos, Konstantinos, and Dimitrios Xefteris. 2017. “Divide and rule: redistribution in a model with differ- entiated candidates.”Economic Theory 63:867–902.

Matthews, Steven A. 1980. “Pairwise symmetry conditions for voting equilibria.”International Journal of Game Theory 9:141–156.

McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. “Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control.”Journal of Economic Theory 12:472–482.

. 1986. “Covering, Dominance, and Institution-Free Properties of Social Choice.” American Journal of Political Science30:283–314.

McKelvey, Richard D, Peter C Ordeshook, and Peter Ungar. 1980. “Conditions for voting equilibria in contin- uous voter distributions.”SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics 39:161–168.

McMurray, Joseph. 2018. “Polarization and pandering in common interest elections.” Accessed March 6, 2020.

https://economics.byu.edu/directory/joseph-c-mcmurray.

Morelli, Massimo, and Richard Van Weelden. 2013. “Ideology and information in policymaking.” Journal of Theoretical Politics25:412–439.