• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

When Does Leadership Matter? The Contingent Opportunities View of CEO Leadership

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "When Does Leadership Matter? The Contingent Opportunities View of CEO Leadership"

Copied!
46
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

Harvard University

Working Paper No. 02-04

When Does Leadership Matter? The Contingent

Opportunities View of CEO Leadership

Noam Wasserman

Harvard Business School

Nitin Nohria

Harvard Business School

Bharat N. Anand

Harvard Business School

April 2001

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection at:

(2)

“W

HEN

D

OES

L

EADERSHIP

M

ATTER

?

T

HE

C

ONTINGENT

O

PPORTUNITIES

V

IEW OF

CEO L

EADERSHIP

Noam Wasserman Harvard Business School

Nitin Nohria Harvard Business School

Bharat Anand Harvard Business School

Noam Wasserman Harvard Business School Baker West 180-C1 Boston, MA 02163 Tel: (617) 495-6215 Fax: (781) 998-2419

Email: nwasserman@hbs.edu

Nitin Nohria

Harvard Business School Morgan Hall 339

Boston, MA 02163 Tel: (617) 495-6653 Fax: (617) 496-6554 Email: nnohria@hbs.edu

Bharat Anand

Harvard Business School Morgan Hall 245

Boston, MA 02163 Tel: (617) 495-5082 Fax: (617) 495-0355 Email: banand@hbs.edu

(3)

“W

HEN

D

OES

L

EADERSHIP

M

ATTER

?

T

HE

C

ONTINGENT

O

PPORTUNITIES

V

IEW OF

CEO L

EADERSHIP

ABSTRACT

Studies that have assessed the impact of CEOs on company performance have debated the

question of “Does leadership matter?” “Leadership” proponents state that leadership is a critical

factor, while “constraints” researchers argue that leaders are so constrained that they have little

impact on performance. We propose that this debate might be misdirected. Instead, the question

should be, “When does leadership matter?” We test a framework -- the “contingent opportunities view” -- that resolves the debate. We show that CEO impact differs markedly by industry, and

that CEOs have the most significant impact where opportunities are scarce or where CEOs have

slack resources.

This paper can be downloaded from the

(4)

INTRODUCTION

Does it matter who the CEO of a firm is? A review of the literature on leadership reveals

markedly different conclusions about how much impact CEOs will have on their companies’

performance. “Conventional” management theorists, to use Thomas’ (1988) term, posit that

CEOs can have a significant influence on the performance of their companies. From their perch

at the top of a company, CEOs are able to shape the company’s strategy, structure, and culture.

By doing so, CEOs are able to actively direct which opportunities their company will pursue

(Barnard, 1938). In contrast, more recently, organizational ecology researchers and others have

argued that CEOs are so constrained by their environments that they have little ability to affect

company performance. For instance, a company’s culture, the structure of its industry, and its

fixed assets are all inertial forces that reduce the CEO’s ability to take actions that will impact

the company (Hannan and Freeman, 1989).

We believe that the debate over CEO impact is misdirected. Instead of debating “Does leadership

matter?” the core question might instead be framed as, “When does leadership matter?” In the spirit of the latter question, we present a “contingent opportunities view” that reconciles these

divergent views, and then test its predictions in a large-sample study.

We depart from past approaches to understanding leadership in three major ways. First, past

studies – including the theoretical papers described above and almost all of the major empirical

studies of CEO leadership to date – have neglected to examine the contexts in which CEOs may

matter. Except for Lieberson and O’Connor’s (1972) study nearly three decades ago, they have

ignored the potential differences in CEO impact across industries (e.g., Weiner, 1978; Weiner

and Mahoney, 1981; Thomas, 1988). In contrast, using the contingent opportunities view as a

framework, we examine to what extent and under what circumstances leaders can have big or

small impacts on company performance, by examining how CEOs affect variations in company

performance.

Second, even those who have taken a contingent view of leadership have neglected critical

elements of the opportunity structure faced by corporate leaders. Perhaps the best known of

(5)

with their overall contingent approach, we disagree with their core conclusion that CEO impact

is greatest in situations characterized by plentiful opportunities. In particular, our contingent opportunities view of leadership posits that where opportunities are scarce, CEOs have a larger impact on company performance, but that in settings where opportunities are plentiful, they have

limited impact on company performance.

Third, the past studies have suffered from methodological problems that cast doubt on their

estimates of CEO impact. All four of the major studies (Lieberson and O’Connor, 1972; Weiner,

1978; Weiner and Mahoney, 1981; Thomas, 1988) have been plagued by one or more of the

following issues: small sample size, failure to control for company size, and narrow definitions

of company performance. We use an augmented variance-decomposition approach, a

42-industry panel data set, and add a new dependent variable to fix these problems and shed new

light on the issue of CEO leadership. Our results show conclusively that CEO effects vary

markedly by industry. Having established this basic tenet of the contingent opportunities view of

CEO leadership, we then explore the factors that account for the differing effects that CEOs can

have on their companies’ performance, and test hypotheses regarding the drivers of CEO impact.

Our theory and results have several important implications for organizations. For example, in

industries where CEO effects are large, boards of directors should be much more careful in

choosing a new CEO than in low-effect industries. Similarly, in high CEO-effect industries –

where CEO actions can have a big impact on company performance – boards should craft CEO

compensation packages that are very sensitive to company performance, while in low-effect

industries, the packages should be less sensitive to company performance.

LEADERSHIP VERSUS CONSTRAINT

Studies of leadership have diverged in their assessments of leaders’ impacts on company

performance. At one end stands the “leadership school,” which argues that leaders have a big

impact on company performance. At the other end, the “constraints school” claims that leaders

are too ruled by their constraints to affect performance.

While the literature on leadership is vast, very little theoretical work has been done about CEO

(6)

Economics journals included in the electronic JSTOR database yielded only six articles with the

words “CEO” or “Chief Executive” in their titles or abstracts. All but one of these was

concerned with compensation or stratification issues instead of leadership. Therefore, in trying

to get a picture of the CEO “leadership” versus “constraint” perspectives, we draw on the

CEO-specific work that has been done, but also draw heavily from the general leadership literature.

The Leadership School

Leadership researchers hold that by adapting their organizations’ missions, strategies, structures,

and cultures to their companies’ environments, CEOs can have a substantial impact on company

performance. Child (1972) states that CEOs make material strategic choices that can influence

firm performance. These strategic choices include “not only the establishment of structural

forms but also the manipulation of environmental features and the choice of relevant

performance standards.” (Child, 1972:2) Drucker is also a forceful advocate of the leadership

view: “In a competitive economy, above all, the quality and performance of the managers

determine the success of a business, indeed they determine its survival.” (Drucker, 1954:1)

Managers are the force within the firm that creates, perceives and pursues opportunities, and

therefore the force that drives differences in organizational performance. For example,

organizational leaders formulate a collective purpose that binds organizational members

(Barnard, 1938). Corporate leaders also adapt organizational structures in response to

technological and environmental changes (Lawrence and Lorsch, 1967; Woodward, 1965;

Thompson, 1967). Just as organizations’ contingencies vary markedly, the structures and

strategies crafted by organizational leaders will also differ, thereby producing large variations in

company performance. Leaders can also be critical change agents, by developing a vision and

strategy, establishing a sense of urgency, forming a “guiding coalition” to help them, creating

short-term wins to build momentum, and institutionalizing new approaches (Kotter, 1996).

However, because CEOs differ markedly in their skills and abilities, and in their perceptions and

beliefs, their actions will differ markedly. The resulting performance of their organizations will

vary considerably. Rotemberg and Saloner (1998) argue that a core task of CEO leadership is

having the vision to make idiosyncratic choices. Those leaders who have such a vision – “a bias

in favor of projects that are consistent with the CEO’s view of the likely evolution of the

(7)

who pursue personal interests, the CEO’s own interests can contribute significantly to variations

in company performance (Jensen and Meckling, 1977). For these reasons, leaders who make

idiosyncratic choices should increase the variation in company performance.

Another way in which CEO differences affect company performance is the way they entered

their current position. While CEOs who come into a company after the forced turnover of their

predecessors tend to improve company performance, CEOs usually hurt company performance

in two cases: natural turnover followed by an outsider successor, and forced turnover followed

by an insider successor (Khurana and Nohria, 1999). In addition, outsider CEOs have a higher

likelihood of making significant changes to organizational strategy (Wiersema, 1992).

For all of these reasons, leaders are expected to account for a large amount of the variation in

their companies’ performance.

The Constraints School

The constraints school holds that factors external to the CEO impose so many constraints on

CEO actions that CEOs have limited impact on company performance. Both external and

internal constraints tie a CEO’s hands, and prevent the CEO from having an impact on company

performance.

Hannan and Freeman state that inertia prevents executives from changing strategy and structure

quickly enough to react to changes in their environments. The sources of inertia include both

internal factors, such as internal politics, existing control systems, previous investments in fixed assets, and organizational norms, and external factors, such as competitive pressures and barriers to exit and entry. In short, “Inertial pressures prevent most organizations from radically

changing strategies and structures.” (Hannan and Freeman, 1989:22) Therefore, they conclude,

“[I]ndividual managers do not matter much in accounting for variability in organizational

properties” (Hannan and Freeman, 1989:43). Others state that existing power relationships will

cause inertia when attitudes and behaviors become increasingly institutionalized (Burkhardt,

1991). Culture researchers point out that the existence of subcultures and countercultures within

an organization can inhibit a leader’s efforts to change the organization (Martin, 1992). Even

(8)

successful and end up producing new patterns of dependence and interdependence (Pfeffer and

Salancik, 1978).

In addition, the confusion and complexity inherent in managerial decision making imposes

cognitive, organizational, and political constraints on decision makers (March and Simon, 1958;

Cyert and March, 1963; Simon, 1976). The impact that leaders can have is also limited by their

own unreflective behaviors that reflect taken-for-granted institutionalized beliefs and practices

(Powell and DiMaggio, 1991). Instead of having idiosyncratic views that shape their actions,

Pfeffer (1977) states that career ladders and institutionally-specified selection processes filter out

idiosyncratic people, resulting in relative homogeneity across CEOs.

As a result, top-level leaders will not be able to have much impact on organizational

performance, for they are severely constrained in their ability to make decisions or to produce

actions that will affect their companies. As a result, leaders are not expected to account for much

variance at all.

Empirical Studies of CEOs

The theoretical literature therefore posits conflicting predictions about how much impact CEOs

will have on company performance. Unfortunately, the empirical literature does not allow us to

settle this issue.

There have been four major empirical studies that have focused on CEO effects (Bowman and

Helfat, 1998). Lieberson and O’Connor (1972) conducted the first study nearly thirty years ago.

In a study of 167 major public companies from 1946-1965, they examined the impacts that each

of Year, Industry, Company, and Leader has on profit margins. Using a sequential

decomposition of variance (discounting first the Year effect, then Industry, then Company, and

then Leadership), they attributed variance in performance to each of the four factors. They found

that Leader effects account for 14.5% of the total variance in profit margins, and that industry

had the biggest impact on profitability, explaining 28.5% of the variance.

In a replication of Lieberson and O’Connor’s study, Weiner (1978) used a sample of 193

manufacturing companies over the period 1956-1974. She found that Leadership accounted for

(9)

Leader (called “stewardship” in their paper) explained 12.8% of the variance in profitability,

more in line with Lieberson and O’Connor’s results. More recently, in a replication study using

a sample of 12 U.K. retailing firms over the period 1965-1984, Thomas (1988) found that Leader

explains only 5.7% of the variance in profitability.

Pfeffer and Salancik present Lieberson and O’Connor’s study as support for their “external

control” position, stating that the study showed that “the magnitude of the administrative effect

was dwarfed by the impact of the organization’s industry and the stable characteristics of a given

organization.” (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978:10) However, this interpretation of Lieberson and

O’Connor’s findings seems extreme. In their paper, to account for the time lag between CEO

actions and the resulting impact on profitability, Lieberson and O’Connor analyzed

forward-lagged measures of performance and found that “leadership influence on profit margins (.32)

exceeds that for either the industry (.273) or company (.222) effects.” Lieberson and O’Connor

themselves concluded that “the leadership effect on company performance does matter.”

(Lieberson and O’Connor, 1972:123)

In short, Lieberson and O’Connor’s (1972) study has been seen to support both the leadership

school and the constraints school. The other three studies since then (Weiner, 1978; Weiner and

Mahoney, 1981; Thomas, 1988) have only compounded the confusion over whether CEO

leadership matters.

THE CONTINGENT OPPORTUNITIES VIEW OF LEADERSHIP

In this paper, we propose and validate a perspective that begins to resolve this issue. Our

perspective builds on a theoretical paper by Hambrick and Finkelstein (1987) that they

themselves describe as “largely speculative.” First, they suggest that constraint – “the obverse of

discretion” – can vary by organization. The top managers of some organizations have more

discretion than do the top managers of other organizations, and that the discretion afforded a

particular top manager can vary over time. Where CEO discretion is high, the CEO (an

“Unconstrained Manager”) can have influence, and where it is low, the CEO (a “Titular

Figurehead”) cannot exceed “his or her discretionary bounds” without losing influence.

Hambrick and Finkelstein propose this theory of managerial discretion as “a bridge between

(10)

1987:403) The concept that CEO impact varies given the nature of the situation is also similar to

Fiedler’s formulation of contingent leadership (Fiedler, 1965; Fiedler, 1967).

This concept is contrary to the assumption that the constraints faced by CEOs are similar across

various situations (e.g., different industries). For example, Thomas states that, “Organizational

constraints are constant across samples, just as the constraints that are imposed on a racing driver

by the characteristics of the car are the same regardless of whether it is raced against identical

cars or very different ones.” (Thomas, 1988:398) Reasoning similarly, all three empirical studies

that built on Lieberson and O’Connor’s results neglected to examine industry-level effects, and

instead either explored the CEO effect at the aggregate level (Weiner, 1978; Weiner and

Mahoney, 1981) or examined CEO effect in a single industry (Thomas, 1988).

In contrast, we state that CEO leadership should vary by context, and propose the following

hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1: The Leader effect will vary by industry. In some industries, we will be

able to reject a null hypothesis that CEO effect is zero, while in other industries, we

will not be able to reject the null hypothesis.

More specifically, our contingent opportunities view focuses on two dimensions that affect the

level of CEO impact. The first class of drivers is the characteristics of a company’s external task

environment. When the external environment provides companies with relatively few

opportunities, it is critical that companies make the most of each opportunity, increasing the

CEO’s impact on performance. The second class of drivers is the resources available to a CEO.

If a CEO has ample resources to pursue opportunities when they arise, or to squander them even

when the opportunities are limited, he or she will be able to have a large impact on company

performance. In contrast, if the CEO has few resources, he or she will have a small impact on

company performance.

Scarce Opportunities and the External Task Environment

The two most important characteristics of the external environment are industry structure and the

(11)

exchange-constraint – the two major drivers of structural autonomy (Burt 1980) – have a powerful impact

on the CEO’s ability to take actions that impact company performance.

According to Burt’s (1992) theory of structural holes, Industry A is dependent on Industry B

when it buys or sells a significant portion of its output to Industry B. Furthermore, if there are

only a few members of Industry B, those members can co-ordinate their actions and thereby

increase their power over Industry A. Therefore, where Industry A sells a high percentage of its

input to Industry B or where Industry B has only a few members, Industry A will have a low

level of power and a low level of discretion in its actions. Also, when a corporation engages in

exchanges with actors who in turn exchange with each other, the corporation loses power and

therefore has less discretion. Conversely, where Industry A sells a small portion of its output to

Industry B, where Industry B has a lot of members, or where Industry A’s exchange partners do

not trade with each other, Industry A will have a high level of discretion.

According to Burt (1992), in industries with high exchange-constraint and concentration, the

opportunities to act are scarce. In such industries, the ability of a CEO to take advantage of

every opportunity is a crucial determinant of company performance, for the competitive

landscape is nearly “zero sum.” On the one hand, if the CEO can take advantage of a scarce

opportunity, it can seize competitive power. On the other hand, if the CEO misses a scarce

opportunity, it may be a long time before the company gets another chance, and in the meantime,

a rival – the one that did take advantage of the opportunity – has gained competitive power. In

the first case, the CEO’s actions would have a big positive impact on company performance,

while in the second case, the CEO would have a big negative impact on company performance.

In contrast, in industries where opportunities are plentiful and competition is “positive sum,” if a

CEO misses an opportunity, his company will be able to pursue another opportunity with relative

ease. Therefore, CEO actions will have much less impact on company performance.

In short, while at first it may seem counter-intuitive, this line of reasoning leads us to conclude

that where opportunities are scarce, CEO effects should be high. In contrast, in situations where

opportunities are plentiful, CEO effects should be low.

More concretely, we can take a quick look at two, very different, industries and see how their

(12)

(SIC 3660) is one in which we would expect to see a high CEO effect. Companies in this

industry design and manufacture telecommunications gear that they sell to

communications-service providers. At key junctures, these communications-service providers make huge investments in upgrading

their networks, buying from the Communications Equipment industry large amounts of

equipment to handle data networking, high-bandwidth transmission, and other critical

components of their telecommunications infrastructures. During the period covered by our

study, the Communications Equipment industry has had higher-than-average concentration and

very high exchange-constraint, leading us to predict that CEO effect will be large in the industry.

In contrast, the Meat Products industry (SIC 2010) is one in which we would expect to see a low

CEO effect. In this industry, concentration and exchange-constraint have both been far below

average, leading us to predict that CEO effect will be much lower than in the Communications

Equipment industry.

When we examine the I/O tables used by Burt for each of these industries, we find marked

differences in the patterns of their use of input commodities (which they have to buy from other

industries) and in their sales of outputs to other industries. As shown below, the Meat Products

industry (which is part of I-O industry number 14) buys 27% of its inputs from its main

input-industry and 24% from its second biggest. These two supplier industries are highly fragmented

with relatively low levels of concentration. On the other hand, the Communications Equipment

industry (part of I-O industry number 56) buys 40% of its main input from a single

input-industry, which in turn is relatively concentrated.

Use of Commodity Inputs

Meat Products

(from I-O industry #14)

Communications Equipment

(from I-O industry #56)

% Bought from Top 5 Industries 60,821 26.97% 8,193 40.23%

54,695 24.26% 1,970 9.67%

22,262 9.87% 1,472 7.23%

16,850 7.47% 1,418 6.96%

8,683 3.85% 782 3.84%

(13)

While the contrast is less stark when it comes to the selling of output, we see a similar pattern.

The Meat Products industry sells all but .3% of its output to a single I-O industry (eating and

drinking places/retailers). This industry has very low concentration, giving Meat Products many

alternative customers for its output. The Communications Equipment industry sells almost 6%

of its output to industries outside of its main buying industry, but the industry to which it sells

94% of its output is highly concentrated, making the opportunity to form supplier relationships

even more scarce and critical.

Selling of Outputs

Meat Products

(from I-O industry #14)

Communications Equipment

(from I-O industry #56)

% Sold to Top 5 Industries 325,129 99.74% 38,346 94.22%

497 0.15% 1,140 2.80%

136 0.04% 433 1.06%

84 0.03% 273 0.67%

39 0.01% 127 0.31%

Total Output 325,972 100.00% 40,700 100.00%

When we combine the I/O exchange-constraints of these industries with data on the degree of

industry concentration, we would predict that the CEO effect in Meat Products would be much

lower than the CEO effect in Communications Equipment.

We therefore pose the following two hypotheses regarding industry concentration,

exchange-constraint, and CEO effects.

Hypothesis 2: In industries characterized by high exchange-constraint, CEOs will

have higher CEO effects than in industries with low exchange-constraint.

Hypothesis 3: In industries characterized by high concentration, CEOs will have

higher CEO effects than in industries with low concentration.

Another driver of opportunities is the growth rate of an industry. When an industry is growing

quickly, CEOs have many opportunities to make strategic choices. For instance, a company’s

(14)

productive capacity, and which research and development projects to pursue. As argued above,

in industries where opportunities are abundant, if a CEO misses an opportunity, his company will

be able to pursue another opportunity with relative ease. Therefore, CEO actions will have much

less impact on company performance. In contrast, in slow-growth industries, opportunities are

scarcer, taking advantage of every opportunity is crucial, and CEO actions will have more impact

on company performance. We therefore pose the following hypothesis about industry growth

and CEO effect.

Hypothesis 4: In high-growth industries, CEOs will have lower CEO effects than in

industries with low levels of growth.

Resource Availability

When opportunities present themselves, CEOs must have the resources to pursue them. For

instance, they must be able to make a critical acquisition when it presents itself, to invest money

in developing a critical technology, or to roll out a large-scale marketing campaign at the right

time. In general terms, this view of the effects of resource availability is similar to Hambrick

and Finkelstein’s (1987) view of “managerial discretion.”

In many industries, debt-holders have a large claim on company resources. When a company is

highly leveraged, it must make high interest and principal payments, and therefore has little

money left with which to pursue opportunities. According to the “control hypothesis” in the

agency-theory literature, this reduces the amount of cash flow that the CEO can direct towards

investments or acquisitions, reducing the CEO’s power to affect company performance (Jensen,

1986). In addition, when a company has a high level of debt, the probability of defaulting on its

debt is high. Therefore, lenders will conduct much more stringent due diligence on the company

(and possibly make more demands on company management) before they are willing to lend the

company more money, further reducing the impact that a CEO can have on the company. For

both of these reasons, high leverage should constrain CEO actions.

We therefore pose the following hypothesis regarding leverage and CEO effect.

Hypothesis 5: CEOs in situations characterized by high levels of debt will have lower

(15)

Counteracting the “handcuffs of leverage” is the amount of slack at the CEO’s disposal. Slack

resources are those that the CEO can redirect relatively easily from low-opportunity areas toward

higher-opportunity areas. For instance, the CEO might be able to take uncommitted marketing

resources and invest them instead in further product development. While there is disagreement

in the literature about whether high levels of slack are helpful or harmful to an organization

(Nohria and Gulati, 1997), there is implicit agreement that high slack should be related to high

CEO effect. On the one hand, the opponents of slack argue that it is a sign of managerial

self-interest and waste. Having high slack will therefore harm company performance, resulting in

CEOs having a negative impact on company performance (Jensen and Meckling, 1976) and increasing the variance in company performance.

On the other hand, proponents of slack argue that slack provides CEOs with resources to manage

external demands and facilitates the experimentation that can be a boon to corporate

performance. For example, Galbraith argues that conflicting demands from external groups can

cause severe constraints for organizational leaders. However, one way for CEOs to cope with

competing demands is through the use of slack resources, such as extra people or assets that can

be redeployed easily (Galbraith, 1973). When CEOs can draw on organizational slack, they can

better satisfy competing demands, thereby reducing interdependence and increasing their impact.

They can take advantage of opportunities that would be missed by CEOs who don’t have such

slack (March and Simon, 1958). Similarly, “the larger the fund of uncommitted capacities, the

greater the organization’s assurance of self-control in an uncertain future” (Thompson, 1967).

Structurally, slack resources enable organizations to create loosely-coupled subunits that reduce

the pressure from environmental constraints, “for without slack, subunits could not be loosely

connected and could not respond to their immediate environments without affecting the entire

system” (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978:275). Finally, high slack provides CEOs with more rewards

to disperse to subordinates who carry out the decisions of the CEO (Tannenbaum, 1968). For

these reasons, we would expect CEOs to have higher impact where there is high slack, and that

this will result in CEOs having a positive impact on company performance and thereby increasing the variance in company performance.

In short, both sides of the debate would agree that high slack should be affiliated with high CEO

(16)

impact on company performance, or due to the CEO’s having a large-but-bad impact on

company performance.) We therefore pose the following hypothesis regarding slack and CEO

effect.

Hypothesis 6: CEOs in situations characterized by high levels of slack will have

higher CEO effects than will CEOs in situations characterized by low levels of slack.

To illustrate this using the examples from above, we can examine resource availability in the

Communications Equipment and Meat Products industries. In the Meat Products industry, the

ratio of debt-to-assets has been above average and the level of slack (as measured by Selling,

General, and Administrative costs as a percentage of sales) has been far below average. In

contrast, in Communications Equipment, the level of debt has been about average while the level

of slack resources has been above average. Therefore, we would predict that CEO effect would

be higher in Communications Equipment than in Meat Products.

The Contingent Opportunities Matrix

The matrix below summarizes the predictions of the contingent opportunities view of leadership.

There are two critical dimensions driving the level of CEO effect: scarcity of opportunities,

which is a function of industry structure, dynamics, and growth, and resource availability, which

is a function of the levels of debt and slack. In “Impact” industries, where opportunities are

scarce and the CEO has the resources needed to pursue the opportunities that arise, the CEO

should have a large impact on company performance. At the other extreme, in “Impotence”

industries, opportunities are not scarce and the CEO is extremely resource constrained, so the

CEO should have little or no impact on company performance. In between the two extremes are

“Constrained” industries, where opportunities are scarce but the resources to pursue the

opportunities are not available, and “Munificence” industries, where resources are available but

the lack of scarce opportunities means that CEOs will not have a large impact on company

(17)

Scarcity of Opportunities

(industry concentration, exchange-constraint)

Low High

Low “Impotent” (Low CEO Effect)

“Constraint”

(Moderate CEO Effect)

Resource Availability

(low leverage, high slack)

High “Munificent” (Moderate CEO Effect)

“Impact”

(High CEO Effect)

It should be noted that some of our hypotheses conflict with predictions made by Hambrick and

Finkelstein (1987). They posit that high constraint situations will produce CEOs who are Titular

Figureheads that have little impact on company performance. In contrast, our contingent

opportunities view follows Burt’s reasoning that in industries with high constraint and

concentration, CEOs who take advantage of – or miss – scarce opportunities should have the

most impact on company performance. To revisit our industry comparisons from before, we

would predict that the CEO effect in the Communications Equipment industry would be high,

while Hambrick and Finkelstein might see the scarce-and-constrained opportunities in the

industry as producing Titular Figureheads.

METHODS

Past studies examining this issue have had mixed findings, and have suffered from

methodological and conceptual problems. A goal of this study is to rectify these problems. We

used an enhanced variance-decomposition approach, a more complete sample with more recent

data, and a better dependent variable to rectify these problems.

Sample

Our sample consists of a hierarchical data set (with CEOs within companies within industries

within years) of 531 companies from 42 industries. In contrast to Thomas’ study, we wanted to

(18)

all industries (defined at the 3-digit SIC level) that had at least eight companies with Compustat

data for the period 1979-1997. Forty two industries fulfilled these criteria and were included in

our data set. These industries included a wide variety of heavy manufacturing companies,

service providers, and other businesses, and a mix of both small and large companies. Appendix

1 shows these 42 industries.

Variables Used to Test Hypothesis 1

To test Hypothesis 1 (that CEO will vary by industry) and to calculate the CEO effects used to

test the remaining hypotheses, we used two different dependent variables to perform variance

decompositions. As independent variables, we used year, industry, company, and CEO

dummies.

Dependent Variable: Firm Performance

To measure firm performance, Schmalensee (1985) used return on assets (ROA), measured as

the ratio of operating income to total assets. The past empirical studies of CEO effect all used

the same or similar forms of profitability as their dependent variable. Therefore, we used ROA

as our first dependent variable.

However, the literature is replete with studies showing that such accounting-based measures of

performance as ROA are flawed. Accounting-based measures neglect the impact of inflation

(Whittington, 1983) and risk (Schmalensee, 1981). Accounting profit also reflects the past

actions of corporate leaders, for today’s performance is a result of the investments that past

managements made in corporate assets (McGahan, 1998). Because of time lags between CEO

actions and resulting changes in profitability (and asset base), ROA will not pick up the full

impact of Leader on company performance (possibly explaining the strong forward-lagged

effects that Lieberson and O’Connor found when using accounting-based profitability measures).

Finally, metrics like ROA include the value of tangible assets only, failing to incorporate such

intangible assets as brand equity and technical competencies. For some industries, such

intangible assets are a significant portion of corporate asset bases.

Therefore, in her study, McGahan (1998) proposes Tobin’s Q (the firm’s market value divided

(19)

reflects expectations that corporate actions will generate greater return from the company’s

assets than if those assets were outside the firm. A value less than 1 reflects expectations that

those assets could generate greater returns if they were deployed outside the firm. While

accounting profit reflects a firm’s past decisions, Tobin’s Q reflects a firm’s prospects for profitability (McGahan, 1998). Tobin’s Q should incorporate more information about company

performance, for when they are making investment decisions, stock-market investors consider a

wide range of company information that is not captured in ROA. For instance, Tobin’s Q can

incorporate some valuation of the corporation’s intangible assets, which is usually absent from

accounting statements and measures. Furthermore, because the market values of company stock

react more quickly to CEO actions, Tobin’s Q should suffer less from time lags. Therefore, we

used Tobin’s Q as the dependent variable in our second set of regression models. (More

specifically, because Tobin’s Q is log-normally distributed, we used the natural logarithm of

Tobin’s Q as our dependent variable.)

We repeated our approach separately for each of these two performance measures.

Independent Variables: Year, Industry, Company, and Leader

Company performance is a function of factors external to the firm and factors internal to the

firm. The two major categories of external factors are conditions related to the business cycle

and the structure of the company’s industry. Two major categories of important internal factors

are characteristics of the firm and the abilities of the company’s leaders.

Therefore, the “external” independent variables we tested are Year and Industry. Year effects reflect macro-economic conditions, such as the state of the financial markets and the stage in the

business cycle. Our panel data set includes company data from 1979-1997, so we tested Year

effects across 19 years. Industry effects reflect conditions that affect the competitive landscape among all companies in an industry. Such factors include switching costs, investments in fixed

assets that are common to all competitors in the industry, and barriers to entry and exit. Industry

effects arise when an industry’s performance consistently differs from the average performance

across all industries, given the year. To assess the Industry effect, we created dummy variables

(20)

The “internal” independent variables we tested are Company and Leader. Company effects reflect the competitive advantages or disadvantages unique to a particular company, and arise

when a company’s performance consistently differs from the average performance across all

companies in its industry, given the year. To assess the Company effect, we created dummy

variables for the 531 companies in our sample. Leader effects reflect the impact that the CEO of a company has on company performance. Leader effects arise when the CEOs makes decisions

that result in actions that affect company performance, and arise when a company’s performance

under a particular CEO consistently differs from the average performance across all of the

company’s CEOs. To assess the Leader effect, we collected the names of the chief executive

officer of each of our 531 companies across all 19 years in our sample. We gathered this

information from annual reports and from Dun & Bradstreet, Standard & Poor, and Moody’s

publications, and used the CEO at the end of the year in question. Our data set included a total

of 1,384 CEOs, for an average of 2.6 CEOs for each of our 531 companies. The average CEO

tenure across the entire data set was 7.0 years, with a high of 10.1 years in SIC 6790 (Other

Investing) and a low of 4.8 years in SIC 4810 (Telecommunications Services). Including 19

years of data in the data set allowed us both to have more CEOs within each company and to

reduce the problem of left and right truncation regarding CEO tenures.

Variables Used to Test Remaining Hypotheses

To test Hypotheses 2 through 6, we want to analyze the factors that affect the amount of CEO

effect. To do this, we used the same 42 industries as we used to test Hypothesis 1. The vector of

CEO effects computed in our test of Hypothesis 1 was our dependent variable, and our

independent variables were the factors hypothesized to have a large effect on CEO effect:

industry structure and resource availability.

Dependent Variable: CEO effect

To test these hypotheses, we wanted to analyze the factors that affect the level of CEO effect.

Therefore, our dependent variable is the vector of CEO effects (shown in Table 3) that we

calculated while testing Hypothesis 1. Given Tobin’s Q’s explanatory superiority in our test of

Hypothesis 1, for the remainder of our analyses, we used the CEO effects calculated in our

(21)

Independent Variables: Opportunity Scarcity and Resource Availability

As described above, we posit that CEO effect will be affected by industry structure and

dynamics, which drive the scarcity of opportunities, and by resource availability, which drives

the CEO’s ability to pursue opportunities. Therefore, to test these hypotheses, we modeled the

drivers of CEOs effect by using variables that dimensionalize industry and test the features of

industries that are associated with Leader effects.

We tested two central dimensions of industry structure: concentration ratios and

exchange-constraint measures. For the first of these, Burt (1982) used the input-output tables in the

Department of Commerce’s Survey of Current Business as measures of the structural

relationships (“constraints”) between industries. We therefore used the same constraints data as

he used. While concentration data is not readily available, we obtained Burt’s SIC-level

four-firm concentration ratios on all of our industries. These ratios are both log-normally distributed.

Therefore, we used the natural logarithms of these constraint and concentration ratios as our two

external constraint measures. (Because the effect of concentration on the CEO effect is likely to

depend on industry constraints, we introduced an interaction term that captures this non-linear

effect.) The mid-point of our data panel is 1987, so we used the 1987 benchmarks.

To test industry growth rate, our other indicator of opportunity scarcity, we computed each

industry’s average annual growth rate of sales revenue.

The resource availability factors that we tested were debt level, amount of slack, and cost

structure. For debt level, we used Compustat data to compute the industry average ratio of total

debt to firm assets. For slack, we used Compustat data to compute the industry average ratio of

SG&A to net sales. For cost structure, we used Compustat data to compute the industry average

ratio of COGS to net sales.

We used industry-level averages for these regressions, for two main reasons. First, the Burt

(1992) industry concentration and exchange-constraint numbers are at the industry level.

Second, each company has, on average, only three CEOs across the 19 years in the data set,

(22)

wanted to use the industry-level CEO effects (where all industries had at least 30 CEOs across

the 19 years in our data set).

Approach

At the end of their paper, Hambrick and Finkelstein pose the problem of how to measure CEO

discretion and impact (Hambrick and Finkelstein, 1987:400). One possible approach is event

analysis, which the leadership-succession literature has used to assess whether managers affect

performance. However, event analysis only looks at the leadership effect during the time after a

succession. In contrast, other empirical studies, such as the one by Lieberson and O’Connor

(1972), use variance decomposition to estimate the leadership effect. These studies are therefore

able to use the leader’s entire record – not just his performance after succession, but throughout

his tenure. In this sense, variance decomposition incorporates more data than does event

analysis. For this reason, we used a version of variance decomposition in this study.

Our approach to variance decomposition follows McGahan and Porter (1997). They build on

methods introduced by Schmalensee (1985) and Rumelt (1991) for disaggregating company

performance into components associated with industry, company, and other effects. Instead of

simply indicating whether a specific independent variable is significant, this method helps explain how important each factor is. Schmalensee (1985) disaggregated company performance into industry and firm effects, and was able to explain almost 20% of the variance in

performance by those factors. However, Schmalensee used only one year of data (1975), and

therefore couldn’t estimate the amount of performance explained by the year effect (a proxy for

macro-economic fluctuations). McGahan and Porter used 14 years of data (1981-1994) and

therefore were able to add year variables to the industry and firm variables. They conducted

hierarchical OLS regressions in which they regressed performance against year, against year and

industry variables, and against year, industry, and firm variables. Then, as an indicator of how

important each class of effects was in explaining company performance, they used the

incremental R2 generated by adding each variable to the regression. In total, they found that the

year, industry, and firm factors explained 52% of the variance in performance.

To study whether leadership matters, we extended McGahan and Porter’s (1997) approach to

(23)

explained by the Year, Industry, Company, and Leader effects. First, we created dummy

variables for each of these independent variables. Then, to test the leadership effect across the

entire sample, we apportioned the variance in company performance (our dependent variable) to

each of our independent variables by seeing how much additional variance was explained each

time we added the variable to the regression. We first ran a linear regression using our

dependent variable and Year, and noted the amount of variance explained by Year (“R2Year”).

Second, we added Industry to the regression, which now included Year and Industry as the

independent variables. The amount of additional variance explained (the difference between the

new regression’s R2 and R2Year) is the amount of additional variance explained by Industry

(“R2Industry”). Third, we added Company to the regression, which now included Year, Industry,

and Company as the independent variables. The amount of additional variance explained (the

new regression’s R2 minus R2Year+R2Industry) is the amount of additional variance explained by

Company (“R2Company”). Finally, we added Leader to the regression, which now included all four

independent variables. The amount of additional variance explained (the new regression’s R2

minus R2Year+R2Industry+R2Company) is the amount of additional variance explained by Leader

(“R2Leader”). It should be noted that this variance-partitioning procedure attributes shared

variation to higher-level factors in the hierarchy; for example, the variance shared by Year and

Industry is attributed to Year.

To test whether CEO effect varied by industry (Hypothesis 1), we ran these regressions at the

industry level. For each industry, we sequentially apportioned the variance in company

performance to Year, Company, and Leader by calculating the incremental variance explained by

adding each independent variable to the regression.

RESULTS

Table 1 presents the results of our aggregate regressions. Across the entire sample, when ROA

was used as the dependent variable, Company accounted for the most variance, followed by

Leader. Industry and Year explained much less of the variance. In total, using ROA, we were

able to explain a little less than half of the variance.

However, using Tobin’s Q, we were able to account for significantly more of the total variance

(24)

but it is followed by Industry and then Leader. Year follows far behind the others. In both the

ROA and the Tobin’s Q results, the Leader effects were significant at the p<.01 level.

[INSERT TABLE 1 HERE]

Table 2 presents the results of our industry-level analyses using ROA as the dependent variable.

In the ROA analysis, the Leader effect varied markedly across industries, from a low of 4.6% in

SIC 2620 (Paper Mills) to a high of 41.0% in SIC 7010 (Hotels and Motels). The Company

effect accounted for the highest percentage of variance in 26 of the 42 industries, the Leader

effect for the highest percentage in 8 industries, and the Year effect for the highest percentage in

8 industries.

[INSERT TABLE 2 HERE]

Table 3 presents the results of our industry-level analyses using Tobin’s Q as the dependent

variable. In the Tobin’s Q analysis, the Leader effect varied from a low of 2.4% in SIC 2010

(Meat Products) to a high of 22.8% in SIC 3820 (Measuring and Controlling Devices). The

Company effect accounted for the highest percentage of variance in 28 of the 42 industries and

the Year effect for the highest percentage in 14 industries. Leader did not account for highest

percentage of variance in any single industry in the Tobin’s Q analysis. In Table 2, the two

columns of CEO effects have a correlation of .21.

[INSERT TABLE 3 HERE]

Table 4 shows the correlation matrix for the independent variables that we used to test

Hypotheses 2 through 6. Table 5 presents the results of this regression model.

[INSERT TABLE 4 HERE]

[INSERT TABLE 5 HERE]

As a whole, this regression of CEO effect on the three opportunity-scarcity indicators and the

two resource-availability indicators has an R2 of 55.6%. Looking first at opportunity scarcity,

concentration and exchange-constraint are both highly significant indicators (p<.01) of CEO

(25)

p<.05 level. Similarly, the resource availability factors are both significant, with debt/assets

highly significant (p<.01) and SG&A/sales significant at the p<.05 level.

DISCUSSION

Aggregate CEO Effects

In our aggregate analyses, Leader accounts for 14.7% of the variance in company performance

when using ROA as the dependent variable, and for 13.5% of the variance when using Tobin’s Q

as the dependent variable. Both of these results are consistent with Lieberson and O’Connor’s

result of 14.5%. The Leader effect is very significant (at p<.01).

In total, using Tobin’s Q as our dependent variable, we were able to account for 67% of the

variance in company performance using the Year, Industry, Company, and Leader factors. As

shown in Table 1, using ROA as the dependent variable accounts for less than half of the

variance in company performance, leaving a large amount of variance unexplained. Given all

the reasons described above for why Tobin’s Q is a good dependent variable (including its lower

susceptibility to lags and its incorporation of information about risks and intangible assets), we

used the results from our Tobin’s Q regressions as the basis for our testing of our other

hypotheses.

Adding Leader to McGahan and Porter’s (1997) year, industry, and firm variables leaves us with

less than a third of the variance unexplained. This compares favorably with past

variance-decomposition analyses, such as McGahan and Porter’s (1997) study, which was left with nearly

half of the variance unexplained. As shown by our results, the amount of unexplained variance

in company performance declines notably when the Leader effect is also included in the analysis.

Inter-industry CEO Effect Results

As noted above, all of the studies that followed Lieberson and O’Connor’s (1972) paper

neglected to examine industry-level results. Our results show that there are marked differences in

CEO effects between industries, no matter which dependent variable is used. Neglecting to

examine inter-industry differences is therefore dangerous. This is particularly true of

(26)

stores. Our results show that CEO effect in the department store industry (here, SIC 5310) may

not be representative of the overall CEO effect, making it hard to generalize from such a study.

In addition, our results show that CEOs have much more impact in some industries than in

others. In industries where the Year and Company effects are large, such as in SIC 4910

(Electric Power Generation, Transmission, or Distribution) where the two variables account for

78% of the variance in performance, CEOs take few actions that affect company performance.

(Later in this paper, we explore reasons why this might be true.) In industries where the Year

and Company effects are large, such as in SIC 3660 (Communications Equipment) where the

two variables account for less than 40% of the variance in performance, CEOs have a lot more

impact. In contrast to Thomas’ racing-driver analogy, CEOs can be faced with very different situations across different industries. CEOs in different industries are not driving identical cars, the other cars on the road are driving faster in some industries than in others, and the roads on which they are driving may be unpaved and steeply uphill, or paved and moderately downhill.

These results support Hypothesis 1, that CEO effect varies by industry. In some settings, CEO

impact is large, while in other settings, CEOs have little impact.

It is worth noting that high CEO impact can be both an advantage and a disadvantage. As noted

by Thompson (1967), deviant discretion – discretion that is inappropriate to the specific situation

– can be harmful. Therefore, industries with high CEO effects may in fact have a lot of CEOs

whose actions negatively impact company performance. The disadvantages of high CEO discretion are also noted by Hambrick and Finkelstein, who state that “if we had to choose as a

society between doing away with Figureheads or Unconstrained Managers, clearly it is the

Figureheads we would keep.” (Hambrick and Finkelstein, 1987:404)

One could argue that our inter-industry results are more or less random: in any sample of 42

industries, we should see some random variation in the amount of CEO effect observed across

industries. (While F-tests would enable us to exclude this possibility were our sample large

enough, the fact that we only have approximately 30 CEOs in each industry means that they are

unreliable here.) To test this argument, we ran Monte Carlo simulations on our data to assess the

CEO effects that would be observed if the effect was purely random. We randomly allocated

(27)

re-ran our variance-decomposition regressions as we had done with the actual performance data.

In 12 of the industries, the CEO effect was more than 5 percentage points (significant at the

p<.05 level) greater than was the random effect generated by the simulation, and in 5 of the

industries it was more than 10 percentage points greater. For a little more than half of the

industries, it was less than 1 percentage point greater than the Monte Carlo effect. This further

reinforces our conclusion that in some industries, CEO leadership matters a great deal, while in

other industries, it has little impact on company performance.

Figure 1 presents the actual CEO results versus the Monte Carlo CEO results. If the CEO effects

were purely random, all of the points plotted should fall along the 45ο line. As shown in the

figure, many of the industries are, indeed, close to this line. These industries are the ones where

CEOs are so constrained that they can have no more than a random effect on performance.

However, as is also shown, many industries lie noticeably above the 45ο

line. In these industries,

where the actual CEO effect is markedly higher than the Monte Carlo CEO effect, CEOs do have

a significant impact on company performance.

[INSERT FIGURE 1 HERE]

As a final test, we subtracted the (“baseline”) Monte Carlo CEO effects from the “actual” CEO

effects in Table 3 to get “randomness-adjusted” CEO effects. This measure was correlated .83

with the actual CEO effects, providing further support for our findings.

However, we should highlight four other issues with our analysis. First, our Leader variable uses

the CEO of the company to assess the impact of leadership on company performance. However,

if a change in CEOs also signals a change in the broader management team (for example, if each

CEO brings in a new CFO, COO, and CTO with him), then our Leader effect would indicate the

impact that management teams have on company performance, rather than the impact that an

individual CEO has on company performance. For this reason, the CEO effect may be less than

the Leader effect found in this study. Second, our variance-decomposition models do not lag

company performance when testing the amount of Leader impact. However, despite the ability

of Tobin’s Q to reduce the problem of lagged performance, for many CEO decisions (such as

major capital investments and attempts to change company culture) the impact of CEO actions

(28)

non-lagged Leader effect found in this study. Third, because we only introduced the Leader

variable after introducing all of the other variables to our regression models, our estimate of the

actual magnitude of the Leader effects may be a conservative estimate of the true Leader effect

in each industry. As a result of these limitations, while our relative estimates of Leader effect

across industries would probably not change much, our absolute estimates of Leader effects must

be interpreted with caution. Fourth, as Hambrick and Finkelstein (1987:378-389) point out, in

addition to the characteristics of the task environment and the characteristics of the internal

organization (both of which we test here), the characteristics of the specific CEO is a third

determinant of CEO effect. There are reasons to believe that differences in CEO characteristics

may not play a large role. For instance, Pfeffer (1977) argues that CEOs are relatively

homogeneous because career ladders filter out people with certain characteristics before they get

to the CEO position. Despite this (and despite it being beyond the scope of this study to assess

how individual characteristics affect the CEO’s impact on company performance), we plan to

study this issue in future work.

Opportunity Scarcity and Resource Availability

Our results also show that the scarcity of opportunities and the availability of resources are both

critical factors in determining how much impact a CEO can have on company performance.

While we have made some initial progress toward understanding the factors that contribute to

CEO effect, future research is required to understand more of the dynamics that underlie our

results from this study.

First, regarding the effects of opportunity scarcity, the results support Hypotheses 2 and 3, that

the industry’s level of exchange-constraint and concentration are critical indicators of CEO

impact. In industries highly constrained by their external relationships, companies have few

opportunities to act. Similarly, our results support Hypothesis 4, that in industries with low

growth rates, the opportunities to act are scarce and therefore CEO effect is high. In these

industries, there is a premium on a CEO’s ability to take advantage of every opportunity, for a

lost opportunity can be a grave setback. In such industries, CEO effect is high. In contrast, in

(29)

Second, with regards to internal firm characteristics, we find three significant factors. Our

results confirm the proposition that high debt handcuffs a CEO, strongly supporting Hypothesis

5. When a company is obligated to pay out a large percentage of its free cash flow to its debt

holders or risk being driven into bankruptcy, CEOs have very little impact on company

performance. In contrast, when debt holders have little claim on free cash flow, CEOs can

deploy the free cash flow to new investments or other activities that will change company

performance.

Our results also show strong support for Hypothesis 6. Slack plays a key role in determining the

impact that a CEO can have on company performance. When slack is low, CEOs will not have

resources with which to pursue scarce opportunities, and they will therefore have little impact on

company performance. However, when slack is high, CEOs can take advantage of opportunities

or proactively pursue projects that may change company performance. They can better satisfy

competing external demands that otherwise would constrain them. Alternatively, CEOs with

high slack may also waste company assets at a faster rate, thereby having a big negative impact

on company performance. In either case, slack is a key factor in CEO impact.

It should be noted that some of the external and internal independent variables we tested are not

completely “exogenous.” However, there are reasons think that this may not be of concern. On

the one hand, while they can play a strong role in determining the level of CEO impact, CEOs

can also help determine those factors. For example, CEOs can affect their firms’ debt levels and

spending on SG&A. They can attempt to change the industry segments in which their firms

compete, thereby affecting the firm’s external constraints. On the other hand, we conducted our

analysis at the industry level, and individual CEOs should have less ability to affect

industry-level variables than they do at the company industry-level. Furthermore, in our sample, the intra-industry

differences in debt level and SG&A are much lower than the differences across industries, which

indicates that CEOs have at best partial control over these variables. One reason for the lack of

intra-industry variation may be the need to adhere to accepted industry standards to maintain

legitimacy (Powell and DiMaggio, 1991). We agree with Pfeffer and Salancik (1978) that even

CEOs who are constrained can take action to change those constraints. For example, in order to

gain control over the resources their organizations need, managers can adapt or alter the

(30)

or growth; negotiate the environment by forming associations and joint ventures, and by creating

interlocking directorships; and use political action to change the legality or legitimacy of its

environment. “There are many possibilities for managerial action, even given the external

constraint on most organizations. Constraints are not predestined and irreversible.” (Pfeffer and

Salancik, 1978:18)

While most of the variables we tested are well-defined, the variable that we used for slack is not.

SG&A is an imperfect indicator of slack because it can include many things, such as committed

advertising expenditures, that are not slack resources re-deployable by the CEO. In addition, the

definition of SG&A may differ by industry; for example, some industries may include

marketing expenses in SG&A, while others have a separate line for reporting marketing expenses

and therefore don’t include them in SG&A. While SG&A is the best universal measure of slack

we have, there is definitely room for further work that examines each of its components to see

what their true effects are, or to examine how inter-industry differences in the definitions of

SG&A affect estimates of CEO available.

It could be argued that, instead of resulting from the five factors we tested, our CEO effects are

artifacts of three other factors: company size, CEO tenure, and the variance in Tobin’s Q. First,

regarding company size, Thomas has argued that company size should be a major contributor to

the level of CEO impact (Thomas, 1988). For instance, in a smaller company, a CEO would

know more about everything going on within the company, and therefore would be in a better

position to impact its performance. Second, regarding CEO tenure, leadership theorists argue

that the longer a CEO’s tenure, the more of an effect the CEO will be able to have on company

performance. This is because over time, CEOs can build management teams that facilitate

execution of CEO decisions, enact the change programs that they formulate, and solidify their

power in the organization. If industries vary systematically in the tenure of their CEOs, then our

CEO effects may be simply due to these differences in CEO tenures. Regarding variance in

Tobin’s Q, it could be argued that our results simply reflect industry differences in the variance

of performance. In industries where performance swings wildly from year to year or from

company to company, the performance data has a higher variance and we would expect to

(31)

of opportunities and resource availability, and simply reflect the underlying variance in

performance.

To test these arguments, we performed an auxiliary analysis that added to our regression model

the average assets, CEO tenures, and variances in Tobin’s Q of each of our 42 industries. This

regression is shown in Table 6. Size, tenure, and variance in performance have no statistically

significant impact on CEO effect. Therefore, we conclude that we can reject these three

alternative explanations.

[INSERT TABLE 6 HERE]

CONCLUSION

In this paper, we have examined the importance of CEOs to variations in performance across

organizations and industries. We have also built on this analysis by identifying characteristics of

the contexts in which CEO leadership matters.

This paper contributes to the literature on leadership in four major ways. First, in methodology,

it differs from previous studies of CEO effects in its use of a dependent performance variable,

Tobin’s Q. This variable has much more explanatory power than did the accounting-based

profitability measures of past studies. Second, this study uses Monte Carlo simulations to assess

whether the CEO effect merely reflects differences in “luck” across CEOs, an issue ignored by

all past studies. Third, it differs from past studies examining the determinants of performance in

industrial economics, in that it includes an important new factor, Leader. While past studies

were not able to explain 50% or more of the variation in performance, adding in the Leader

effect helps us account for a large amount of the unexplained variance.

Finally, we think that the biggest contribution of this study is its exploration of the contexts in

which CEO leadership matters. Past empirical studies that did include leadership effects either

neglected to examine whether CEO effects varied by industry or failed to pursue such results

beyond the “tentative and exploratory” stage. When we examine differences between industries,

we find large and interesting differences in how much of the variance in performance can be

attributed to the CEO of the company. For example, in Communications Equipment, the CEO

Gambar

Table 1.  Incremental explanatory power (Incremental R2) from adding each independent
Table 2.  Incremental explanatory power (Incremental R2) from adding each variable to the regression model, using ROA as the dependent variable.
Table 3.  Incremental explanatory power (Incremental R2) from adding each variable to the regression model, using Tobin’s Q as the dependent variable.
Table 4.  Correlation matrix for independent variables included in Table 5 regression model.
+3

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

Panitia Pengadaan Barang/Jasa pekerjaan Pengadaan Konstruksi/Rehabilitasi Gedung Kantor kegiatan Rehabilitasi Sedang/Berat Gedung Kantor dengan ini mengumumkan Pemenang

Jika bentuk tertulis perikatan hukum yang dipilih untuk pengadaan barang ini adalah Surat Perintah Kerja (SPK) maka Syarat-syarat Khusus Kontrak (SSKK) tidak berlaku

Terkoreksi Terhadap HPS (%) Pematangan Lahan Tempat Pembangunan Astaka

kotoran ayam merupakan pupuk organik yang banyak dimanfaatkan dalam usaha. bercocok tanam dan pada masa kini banyak dimanfaatkan juga

The method used is descriptive method where the data in this paper in the form of exposure to language that carries thoughts, attitudes, and behaviors of the two main characters

[r]

sebagai manajer adalah kepala madrasah harus memiliki strategi yang tepat untuk memberdayakan tenaga kependidikan melalui kerja sama atau kooperatif, memberi kesempatan

Pengetahuan merupakan arti dari kata knowledge yang mempunyai arti, “Kenyataan atau keadaan mengetahui sesuatu yang diperoleh secara umum melalui