• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Ecological Economics:Vol36.Issue2.Feb2001:

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:E:Ecological Economics:Vol36.Issue2.Feb2001:"

Copied!
8
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

COMMENTARY

Economics of transaction costs saving forestry

Y. Zhang *

The Uni6ersity of Helsinki,Department of Forest Economics,PL27,00014Helsinki,Finland

Received 14 February 2000; received in revised form 19 May 2000; accepted 12 July 2000

Abstract

Following the arguments concerning the problems of traditional forest economics in Putz (2000), this article shows that transaction cost economics can overcome some of the shortcomings of the main stream forest economics. The public forestry, subsistence forestry, non-industrial private forestry, China’s share-holding forestry, and their revolutions are analyzed by the relative transaction costs of labor, capital, land and forest products. Potential implications of transaction cost economics in forest policy, including regulated access to commons, sustainable forestry criteria, ecological certificates and land tenure decentralization, have also been discussed. © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords:Public forestry; Non-industrial private forestry; Economic reforms; Transaction costs; China

www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

1. Introduction

‘‘Economics of home grown forestry’’ by Fran-ciz Putz (2000) in this journal challenges main stream forest economists. I intend to advance discussions using transaction cost economics. The concept of transaction costs originated from Coase (1937) where he investigated why firms exist and found that firms emerge to organize whenever their costs were less than the costs of carrying out transactions through the market. This theory has been subsequently developed by Coase (1960), Alchian and Demsetz (1972),

Che-ung (1969, 1983), Williamson (1975, 1985), among others. Transaction costs can be distinguished from production costs, which is the cost category with which neo-classical analysis has been preoc-cupied. North (1990) divided the total costs of production into transformation costs, the costs of inputs of land, labor, and capital involved in transforming the physical attributes of a good,

andtransaction costs, the cost in defining,

protect-ing, and enforcing the property rights to goods. Transaction cost economics provides a very useful tool to understand several seemingly unre-lated and non-economic issues: the law, ethics, organization, governments, family, state. Unfor-tunately, it has been applied only in a very limited number of forestry studies (e.g. Leffer and * Tel.: +358-9-19157983, fax:+358-9-19157984.

E-mail address:Yaoqizhang@yahoo.com (Y. Zhang).

(2)

Y.Zhang/Ecological Economics36 (2001) 197 – 204 198

Rucker, 1991; Geodecke and Ortmann, 1993; Wang and van Kooten, 1999; Zhang, 2000a). The Putz article collectively identified that various op-portunity costs should be used in evaluation at various management regimes, but he did not use the concept of transaction costs. ‘Home grown forestry’ has its basis both in institutional eco-nomics as has been discussed in many important works (e.g. Commons, 1934; Knights, 1965; Williamson, 1985), and in the specific nature of silviculture as will be briefly discussed in the fol-lowing section. Then, I will use public-owned forestry, subsistence forestry, non-industrial pri-vate forestry, and the currently popular share-holding forestry in China to show that transaction cost economics help to explain that many prob-lems exist in the traditional economic analysis.

2. The nature of silviculture

Traditionally, comparative advantage is exam-ined by means of the relative cost of the inputs and technology. Clague (1991) presents an inter-esting model of comparative advantage using the institutional approach. He separates commodities and services into two groupings as ‘self-contained’ and ‘non-self-contained’. ‘Self-contained’ produc-tion does not benefit much from an elaborate division of labor that would require coordination within large organizations or across firms. The operations of restaurants, taxicabs, low-class ho-tels, barber shops, repairing services, and even agricultural production may be classified as ‘self-contained’. He argued that less developed coun-tries (LDCs) have a comparative advantage in the production of primary products because many of these production processes are ‘self-contained’.

It is quite clear that silviculture is in the cate-gory of a primary industry. However, unlike many other primary industries, it is not ‘‘self-con-tained’’ as can be seen from the following points: 1. Trees and forestland are both immobile and slow-maturing. Brokensha and Castro (1984) and Bruce (1986) argue that planting trees more closely resembles the digging of a well or the construction of a fence than the planting of annual crops because the value of the

in-vestment is regained quite slowly. There is a strong positive relationship between the secu-rity of tenure and the willingness to invest in tree-planting. The security of tenure relates not only to political stability and the tenure ap-plied, but also to the status of theft and pro-tection against theft (more about on property rights and theft, see Barzel (1997)).

2. Since many forest products are environmental goods and services, it is sometimes costly to delineate and transfer the property rights. They may be more easily exposed to the public domain. Free rider problems come from the costly transaction costs. Many environmental goods are public goods (or at least mixed public and private goods) — with characteris-tics of non-rivalry in consumption and difficulty in exclusion. The transaction costs involved in trading environmental products may be high compared with the production costs.

3. Difficulties arise in evaluating and monitoring the silviculture activities because they are less standardized than factory work, or even the work in the agriculture. The quality as well as quantity of the silviculture can only be accu-rately evaluated after a long period of time. Difficulty in evaluation is also caused by the difficulty in measuring elements of the natural environments, such as soil, water, temperature, etc. So we may not able to correctly identify the contributions from the labor or from the natural factors. Consequently, moral hazard (alternatively, monitoring cost) could be seri-ous by the use of hired labor or by team work, particularly when the work is conducted manually.1

The nature of silviculture causes the transaction costs of hiring, monitoring labor, getting capital and marketing the products to be relatively high. Therefore, silviculture is not ‘‘self-contained’’, and suffers some disadvantages from market ex-change. The socio-economic history before indus-trialization to a large extent is a history of the

1The moral hazard basically comes from information

(3)

evolution of the relationship between land and crops, and contractual relationship between owner of labor and owner of land and capital (see, for example, North and Thomas, 1973; Smith, 1975). The evolution of forest land tenure and persistency of public forestry, community forestry and household forestry can be well ex-plained by the transaction costs.

3. Transaction cost saving forestry

3.1. Public-owned forestry

Public ownership2 is often justified by arguing that forests have multiple functions that conflict with the single product objective that provides profits to most private owners. However, the high share of public forests in the world can be better explained by looking at transaction costs. If we say property rights in public ownership are less well defined3, the ambiguous property right ar-rangement results in less market-oriented ex-change as well as non-market controlling, which means less cost required in defining and transfer-ring of the property rights.

Community forests are very important in most LDCs because the transactions of the labor, capi-tal, as well as forest products through markets, are relatively costly. The labor and capital are often rooted within the community. The interests of a community are more homogenous, collective actions and non-market exchanges are easier to conduct. Ostrom (1986) argued that groups arise when the user population lives close to a resource and is relatively small, supply is moderately scarce

compared to demand, and is subject to multiple uses requiring management and coordination.

As populations grow and economic develop-ment takes place, population migration becomes more common, the individual interests become more heterogeneous, trees and land are more sub-ject to rapid exogenous changes — settlement by outsiders and logging by local and multinational firms. Consequently, non-market exchange within community become most costly, the forest owner-ship becomes worth being devolved into private ownership. In most DCs, community forestry is shrinking4

, but still persists.

3.2. Subsistence forestry and non-industrial

pri6ate forestry

The economic reasons behind forest managed by subsistence farmers in LDCs have been well-elaborated in Putz (2000), among others. Off-farm employment, risk aversion, means of investment and non-market products seem to be the most important reasons. One could perhaps interpret theses as forms of transaction costs. Self-suffi-ciency (home grown) forestry is chosen when the transaction costs are larger than the gain from market exchange.

The non-industrial private forests (NIPFs) in industrial countries are essentially also transaction costs saving forestry. It is generally believed that NIPFs have lower economic efficiency than indus-trial private forests (e.g. Doll and Orazen, 1978; Cubbage, 1983). In Finland, some attempts have been made to circumvent the partitioning process. It was proposed by the Finnish Forest 2000 pro-gram that the partitioning of NIPF holdings into

4Some community forests seem still competitive in some

DCs (see Carlsson 1999 about Swedish community forests), but we cannot deny the fact that community forests had been decreasing in the last century. Presently, community forest management has been receiving attention. The reason is the increase in demand and value of environmental products from forests. Trading of environmental goods and services through markets is still costly, so community forests regain some advantages. Of course, some institutional innovations do help the survival and the competitiveness of community forests. Similarly, some private forests are purchased by states for nature reserves.

2Most public forests are state-owned, meaning that only a

small share is owned by municipalities, communities, villages and other public entities below national level. We should note that this distinction is arbitrary. It is often the case that state and local communities share the same forests.

3It should be noted that property rights in public ownership

(4)

Y.Zhang/Ecological Economics36 (2001) 197 – 204 200

units smaller than 10 ha should be made illegal, but this has never been implemented in practice (Ripatti, 1996). NIPFs are generally less efficient only when viewed from the perspective of main-stream microeconomics without considering transaction costs. Table 1 explains the economic reasons for NIPFs. We should note that the capi-tal, labor (techniques), wood product markets have been well developed, their transactions come less costly in most DCs, and it might be-come less economic to own NIPFs for purely investment and employment purposes, but more likely for recreation purposes. The number of NIPF owners is increasing, but holding size is decreasing (Ripatti, 1996). This fact might sup-port this hypothesis because building a summer house does not require large forests, while other recreation such as hunting, strawberry collecting and walking in the forests are open to everyone in Finland and many other countries.

Big wood-based processing firms, like pulp and paper mills, often prefer to have their own trees and forestland to provide raw materials, or at least they have long-term contracts with some forest owners. A convincing explanation could be the transaction of timber through the markets is more costly than other products, therefore, in-house supply of raw materials is favored.

3.3. Chinas share-holding forestry

McMillan et al. (1989), Lin (1992) and Wen (1993), among others, support the claim that de-collectivization (privatization of land-use rights) was the major reason for the growth of agricul-tural output in China from the late 1970s until the early 1980s. In forestry, similar reforms have been carried out and also have helped forest develop-ment. However, the positive effects on forest man-agement are still limited and vary from place to place (e.g. Yin and Newman, 1997; Zhang et al., 1999, 2000). Several concrete reports (e.g. Ruiz-Peres et al., 1999; Kant and Chiu, 1999) on the positive impacts on forestry are about economic forests (e.g. fruit-trees) and bamboo in southern China. We must keep in mind that economic forest and bamboo are more agriculture than silviculture.

Compared with privatization in agriculture, the share-holding system is growing more popular and acceptable in forestry (see Song et al., 1997). As argued above, the costs associated with defin-ing, protecting and transferring property rights in trees, land and products are much higher in forestry than in agriculture. The agricultural land is also never well defined; however, farmers have little doubt about harvesting their annual crops and the land-use rights under the contracted years (1 – 5 years in the beginning, 10 – 20 years re-cently). While it is much more uncertain in the distributed or contracted forestland and trees, this was particularly true during the early period of economic reforms. The privatization of agricul-tural land immediately promoted agriculagricul-tural de-velopment, both reflected in farmer income from agriculture and outputs, while the privatization of forestland immediately promoted the early har-vesting of the existing trees, but not investment in the contracted land. It is generally believed that the early economic reforms in forestry were the third largest cause for destruction of forests, only after the Great-Leap-Forward in 1958 and the Cultural Revolution (1966 – 1976).

(5)

Y

.

Zhang

/

Ecological

Economics

36

(2001)

197

204

201

The economic reasons for NIPFs

Factors Conditions of using markets Notes

(i) Since it is more costly when only part-time in transaction (the

Labor owner (value for potential employer)−(value by

self-employment)\transaction costs of labor transaction costs also can be divided into fixed and variable

costs), the relative transaction costs for searching jobs (or hiring) are relative high for relative short work time, farmer and periodically unemployed workers are more likely to own some NIPFs. (ii) The opportunity cost of occasional and self-chosen time could be very small, even negative: the work may be for recreation. Minimum wage (or prevailing wage level) is irrelevant for this category of work.

(value for potential user)−(value by own-use)\transaction costs

Capital owner Investment in NIPFs is unlikely very attractive, but still better

than the deposit interest rate, or more secure. The prevailing of capital

interest rate (loan)-based criterion of investment may not be very well grounded for NIPFs.

NIPF owner (the land (value for potential buyer)−(value for holding)\transaction cost (i) High taxation existing between the land transaction leads to

higher transaction costs.(ii) Transaction costs are relatively lower of the land

owner)

between relatives; it is quite often that NIPFs are transferred between relatives who become new NIPF owners rather than between strangers and private industrial forest owners. (iii) The value of cultural and heritage of the forests for the current owner is often higher than potential buyers.

Products consumers (Production cost for the consumers)−(Production cost for the (i) The transaction of recreation goods (e.g. weekend or holiday

producer)Btransaction cost of the product in the forests) is still costly and the demand for the products is

increasing rapidly. It is not difficult to imagine how costly it is to go through the stages of searching, contacting, negotiating and implementing of the exchange on these products, such as renting a house in the forests. Especially, the demand for the recreation is frequent. (ii) Recreation products cannot be moved, do not have standards. Asymmetric information is serious (e.g. see Akerlof, 1970).

[(value for others)−(value for own use)]\(transaction costs) Many NIPF owners have multiple objectives (e.g. Bliss and

Multi-factors owner and

Martin, 1989; Kuuluvainen et al., 1996), and own multiple input consumer

(6)

Y.Zhang/Ecological Economics36 (2001) 197 – 204 202

Illegal extraction in forests, particularly dis-tributed forests that were from previously com-munity-owned, is often regarded as less criminal than theft in agriculture because historically trees are considered ‘wilderness’ and were once commu-nity-owned, while agricultural crops are more ob-viously planted by households. Organized illegal logging by one community on another commu-nity-owned forests is not rare. A tree worth one month’s work may be stolen without a big risk of being caught and with no serious penalty if caught, thus illegal logging is difficult to prevent. The economic reforms have not reduced the num-ber of crimes in general, and the numnum-ber of illegal logging crimes in particular.

The rural market institutions are also generally sufficient for agriculture. The still poor capital and labor markets cannot seriously impede small-scale household agriculture. Transfer of con-tracted agriculture land was not officially allowed between farmers, but this in practice was usually permitted by informal institutions, even at the earliest time of economic reforms. Most agricul-tural products can be easily traded on the local rural market, or even in nearby cities. However, silvicultural investment requires much more se-cure capital market, and the outputs require more distant markets.

It is exactly because of the transaction costs that the share-holding system prevails after two decades of reforms. There are several forms of share-holding systems across China. A typical form is to convert certain forests within the com-munity into monetary shares which are then evenly redistributed between households in rela-tion to family size. These shares were defined as

basic shares’ or ‘initial shares’, which can be

inherited or transferred, but cannot be withdrawn by any holder. Later, a new type of share was issued in return for investment of labor and capi-tal. These are known as an ‘added share’ or

in6estor share’, which are permitted to be

with-drawn. A shareholding committee is then formed, and an executive is elected to take charge of the company.

The share-holding system stands between the private forest ownership and traditional commu-nity forest ownership. It can save some

transac-tion costs in: (1) defining and distributing the trees and land (as discussed above, it is not a easy task to value and mark, particularly monitor the boundaries of trees and land); (2) protection of the trees owing to its scale and internal-cross-monitoring; (3) transaction of capital (it is less costly within a more integrated group (Ben-Po-rath, 1980; Williamson, 1985)); (4) job searching (or labor hiring) for the periodically free labor besides their private agriculture; (5) marketing timber product due to its scale and information and solving the conflicts regarding environmental issues within the community.

The problems of the share-holding system, such as unnecessary bureaucracy, and lack of incentive, are also obvious. Its evolution into a more mar-ket-oriented system is unavoidable when the so-cio-economic environments change. Some evidence has already shown leased-contract and open-auction to individuals are becoming impor-tant ways of land tenure changes in recent years.

4. Final conclusions

(7)

A growing number of the versions on sustain-able forestry criterion and ecological certificates are emerging (e.g. see Kiker and Putz, 1997). However, very few studies have been conducted on calculation of the potential costs associated with formulation and implementation. I doubt whether the gain can be larger than the cost in implementing the criterion and timber certification.

Presently, decentralization and devolution be-come an important theme in forest management (see Fisher, 1999). However, we should not be limited to the two extremes (state-owned, private-owned), or the one between (community-owned); testable implications may be found somewhere in between along the continuum. Institutional change is not costless or instant (North, 1990; Zhang, 2000b). Institutions are important factors for forestry development, but the potential costs and time for institutional transformation, i.e. the transaction costs, should be carefully considered.

Acknowledgements

The author is grateful for the comments of Jari Kuuluvainen and three referees, particularly Oliver Ray Stanton and Peter Midmore. This is a part of output from a study on institutions and forestry development in China supported by Economy and Environment Programme for S.E. Asia (EEPSEA) in Singapore. All errors are the responsibility of the author.

References

Akerlof, G.A., 1970. The market for ‘lemon’: quality uncer-tainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 488 – 500.

Alchian, A.A., Demsetz, H., 1972. production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review 62, 777 – 795.

Barzel, Y., 1997. Economic Analysis of Property Rights, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Ben-Porath, Y., 1980. The F-connection: families, friends, firms and the organization of exchange. Population and Development Review 6 (1), 1 – 30.

Bliss, J.C., Martin, J.A., 1989. Identifying NIPF management motivations with qualitative methods. Forest Science 35 (2), 601 – 622.

Brokensha, D., Castro, A.P., 1984. Fuelwood, agroforestry and natural resource management: the development signifi-cance of land tenure and other resource management uti-lization systems. Paper Prepared for USAID.

Bruce, J.W., 1986. Land tenure issues in project design and strategies for agricultural development in sub-Saharan Africa. LTC Paper No. 128. University of Wisconsin, Madison.

Carlsson, L., 1999. Still going strong. Community forests in Sweden. Forestry 72 (1), 11 – 26.

Cheung, S., 1969. Transaction costs, risk aversion, and the choice of contractual arrangement. Journal of Law and Economics 12, 23 – 45.

Cheung, S., 1983. The contractual nature of the firm. Journal of Law and Economics 26, 1 – 22.

Clague, C., 1991. Relative efficiency, self-containment, and comparative costs of less-developed countries. Economic Development and Cultural Change 39, 507 – 530. Coase, R.H., 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 16,

386 – 406.

Coarse, R.H., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3, 1 – 44.

Commons, J.R., 1934. Institutional Economics. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

Cubbage, E.W., 1983. Economics of forest tract size: theory and literature. United States Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, p. 41 General Technical Report.

Doll, J.P., Orazen, F., 1978. Production economics: Theory with Application. Grid Incorporation, Columbus, OH. Dong, X, Dow, G.K., 1993. Monitoring costs in Chinese

agricultural teams. Journal of Political Economy 101 (3), 539 – 553.

Fisher, R.J., 1999. Devolution and decentralization of forest management in Asia and the Pacific. Unasylva 59 (199), 3 – 5.

Geodecke, E.J., Ortmann, G.F., 1993. Transaction costs and labor contracting in the South-African forestry industry. South African Journal of Economics 61 (1), 67 – 83. Holmstrom, B., 1982. Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of

Economics 13 (2), 324 – 340.

Kant, S, Chiu, M, 1999. Forestry reforms and the local economy of Linan County, Zhejiang, China. Faculty of Forestry, University of Toronto Working Paper. Kiker, C.F., Putz, F.E., 1997. Ecological certification of forest

products: economic challenges. Ecological Economics 20, 37 – 51.

Knights, F., 1965. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Harper & Row, New York.

Kuuluvainen, J., Karppinen, H., Ovaskainen, V., 1996. landowner objectives and nonindustrial private timber sup-ply. Forest Science 42 (3), 300 – 309.

Leffer, K.B., Rucker, R.R., 1991. Transaction costs and the efficient organization of production: a study of timber-har-vesting contracts. Journal of Political Economy 99, 1060 – 1087.

(8)

Y.Zhang/Ecological Economics36 (2001) 197 – 204 204

McMillan, J., Whalley, J., Zhu, L.J., 1989. The impact of China’s economic reforms on agricultural productivity growth. Journal of Political Economy 97, 781 – 807. MOF (Ministry of Forestry), 1992. Forest Resources

Adminis-tration and Monitoring. China’s Forestry Publishing House, Beijing (in Chinese).

MOF (Ministry of Forestry), 1996. Forestry Yearbook 1995. China’s Forestry Publishing House, Beijing (in Chinese). North, D.C., Thomas, R.P., 1973. The Rise of The Western

World. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

North, D.C., 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Eco-nomic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Ostrom, E., 1986. Issues of definition and theory: some conclu-sions and hypotheses. In: Proceedings of the Conference on Common Property Resource Management. National Academy Press, Washington, DC, pp. 599 – 615.

Putz, F.E., 2000. Economics of home grown forestry. Ecologi-cal Economics 32, 9 – 14.

Ripatti, P.; 1996. Factors affecting partitioning of private forest holdings in Finland: a logit analysis, Acta Forestalia Fennica.

Ruiz-Peres, M., Zhong, M., Belcher, B., Xie, C., Fu, M., Xie, J., 1999. The role of bamboo plantations in rural develop-ment: the case of Anji County, Zhejiang, China. World Development 27 (1), 101 – 114.

Smith, V.L., 1975. The primitive hunter culture, pleistocene extinction, and the rise of agriculture. Journal of Political Economy 83 (4), 727 – 775.

Song, Y., Burch, W., Geballe, G., Geng, L., 1997. New organizational strategy for managing the forests of

south-east China — the share-holding integrated forestry tenure (shift) system. Forest Ecology and Management 91, 183 – 194.

Wang, S., van Kooten, G.C., 1999. Silvicultural contracting in British Columbia: a transaction cost economics approach. Forest Science 45 (2), 272 – 279.

Wen, G.J., 1993. Total factor productivity change in China’s farming sector: 1952 – 1989. Economic Development and Cultural Change 42 (1), 1 – 42.

Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. Free Press, New York. Williamson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of

Capital-ism. The Free Press, New York.

Yin, R, Newman, D., 1997. Impacts of rural reforms: the case of the Chinese forest sector. Environment and Develop-ment Economics 2, 289 – 303.

Zhang, Y. 2000a. Deforestation and forest transition: Theory and evidence in China. In: Palo M., Vanhanen H., (eds.), World Forests from deforestation to transition? Kluwer Academic, The Netherlands, 41 – 65

Zhang, Y. 2000b. Costs of plans versus costs of markets: Reforms in China’s state-owned forest management, De-velopment Policy Review, 18(3), 285-306.

Zhang, Y., Dai, G., Huang, H., Kong, F., Tian, Z., Wang, X, Zhang, L., 1999. The forest sector in China: towards a market economy. In: Palo, M., Uusivuori, J. (Eds.), World Forests, Society and Environment. Kluwer Academic, The Netherlands, pp. 371 – 394.

Zhang, Y., Uusivuori, J., Kuuluvainen, J., 2000. The impacts of economic reforms on rural forestry in China, Forest Policy and Economics, 1, 27-40.

Gambar

Table 1The economic reasons for NIPFs

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

Pakaian adat pada pesta perkawinan masyarakat Sumando Pesisir di Kabupaten Tapanuli Tengah merupakan potensi yang sangat besar dalam pariwisata untuk menjadi sebuah atraksi wisata

Sehubungan dengan Addendum dokumen pengadaan pada SKPD Dinas Perkebunan Daerah Propinsi Sulawesi Tengah, maka melalui ini kami sampaikan ralat addendum yang dimaksudkan yaitu

Data Keuangan Pajak sesuai dokumen penawaran yaitu : NPWP, SPT Tahun 2013, Pajak Bulanan PPH pasal 25 atau pasal 21 / pasal 23 atau PPN bulan Juni, Juli dan Agustus 2014 , atau

Diurnal changes in leaf water potential and leaf starch (circles) and sucrose (triangles) concentrations of sugar maple leaves in the healthy (open symbols, Fairfield) and

Summary Hydraulic architecture parameters, water relation parameters and wood anatomy were studied in roots and shoots of the flood-tolerant tree Annona glabra L.. on Barro

KANTOR LINGKUNGAN HIDUP DAN KEBERSIHAN Pengadaan Alat Peraga Pendidikan dan Sarana Penunjang Pembelajaran SD Tahun Anggaran 2010 (DAK + Sharing).. Pengadaan Sarana TIK SD

Menunjuk Surat Panitia Pengadaan Barang/Jasa Pemerintah Bidang Pengembangan Sumber Daya Air Nomor : 18/TAP/APBD/PSDA/IV/2012, tanggal 10 April 2012 perihal Penetapan Pemenang

Pokja Kebinamargaan dan Pengairan pada Unit Layanan Pengadaan (ULP) Kabupaten Ogan Ilir akan melaksanakan Pelelangan Pemilihan Langsung Pascakualifikasi secara elektronik untuk