• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

getdoc2a9c. 249KB Jun 04 2011 12:04:12 AM

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "getdoc2a9c. 249KB Jun 04 2011 12:04:12 AM"

Copied!
21
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

El e c t ro n ic

Jo ur

n a l o

f P

r o

b a b il i t y

Vol. 14 (2009), Paper no. 24, pages 612–632. Journal URL

http://www.math.washington.edu/~ejpecp/

Representation of continuous linear forms on the set of

ladlag processes and the hedging of American claims

under proportional costs

Bruno Bouchard

Université Paris-Dauphine, CEREMADE, and CREST

bouchard@ceremade.dauphine.fr

Jean-François Chassagneux

Université Paris VII, PMA,

and ENSAE-CREST chassagneux@ensae.fr

Abstract

We discuss ad-dimensional version (for làdlàg optional processes) of a duality result by Meyer (1976) between bounded càdlàg adapted processes and random measures. We show that it al-lows to establish, in a very natural way, a dual representation for the set of initial endowments which allow to super-hedge a given American claim in a continuous time model with propor-tional transaction costs. It generalizes a previous result of Bouchard and Temam (2005) who considered a discrete time setting. It also completes the very recent work of Denis, De Vallière and Kabanov (2008) who studied càdlàg American claims and used a completely different ap-proach.

Key words:Randomized stopping times, American options, transaction costs. AMS 2000 Subject Classification:Primary 91B28, 60G42.

(2)

1

Introduction

This paper is motivated by the study ofd-dimensional markets with proportional transaction costs1 in which each financial asset can possibly be exchanged directly against any other. This is typically the case on currency markets. The termproportional transaction costs refers to the fact that the buying and selling prices of the financial assets may differ but do not depend on the quantities that are exchanged.

More precisely, we study the setCbv of processesCbthat can besuper-hedgedfrom an initial endow-mentvon[0,T]. This means that, by dynamically trading somed given underlying financial assets (stocks, bonds, currencies, etc.), it is possible to construct a portfolio Vb such thatVb0= v andVb is “larger” thanCbat any time t∈[0,T]. Here and below,Vbis ad-dimensional process corresponding to the different quantitiesVbi, id, of each financial asset iheld in the portfolio. The superscript

b is used to insist on the fact that we are dealing with quantities, as opposed to “amounts”, and to be consistent with the established literature on the subject. Similarly,Cbshould be interpreted as a d-dimensional vector of quantities.

Obviously, in idealized financial markets where buying and selling each underlying asset iis done at a single price Si in a givennuméraire, such as Euros or Dollars, the value of the portfolio can be simply defined as the current value of the position holdings V = SV := PidSiVbi, Cb can be represented as a real numberC=SCb, the value ofCb, and the term “larger” just means thatVtCt at any time t ∈[0,T]P−a.s., i.e. the net positionVb−Cbof quantities has a non-negative value if evaluated at the priceS. In this case, it can be typically shown thatCb∈Cbvif and only if

sup τ∈T

sup

Q∈M

EQCτS0v ⇐⇒ sup τ∈T

sup

Q∈M

EQ”Sτ(Cbτv)—≤0 , (1.1)

whereT denotes the set of all[0,T]-valued stopping times andM is the set of equivalent proba-bility measures that turnSinto a martingale, see e.g. [16, Chapter 2 Theorem 5.3]or Section 3 for a more precise statement.

The so-called dual formulation (1.1) has important consequences. In the case where Cbt is

inter-preted as the payoff of an American option2, in terms of quantities of the underlying assets to be delivered if the option is exercised at time t, it provides a way to compute the minimal value p(Cb)ofS0v such thatCb∈Cbv, or equivalently the corresponding “minimal” set of initial holdings {v∈Rd : S0v= p(Cb)}. The amount p(Cb) is the so-calledsuper-hedging price. It is not only the

minimal price at which the option can be sold without risk but also an upper-bound forno-arbitrage prices, i.e. the upper-bound of prices at which the option can be sold without creating an arbitrage opportunity. The dual formulation also plays a central role in discussing optimal management prob-lems which are typically studied through the Fenchel duality approach, see e.g.[16, Section 6.5]for an introduction,[4]for models with transaction costs, the seminal paper[19]for frictionless mar-kets, and[2]for wealth-path dependent problems where the notion of American options is involved. In this case, Cb is related to the optimal variable in the associated dual problem. Proving existence in the original optimal management problem and the duality between the two corresponding value functions then essentially breaks down to proving that Cb∈Cbv, where v is the initial endowment.

(3)

This is typically obtained by using the optimality ofCbtogether with some calculus of variations and a dual formulation forCbv.

When transaction costs are taken into account, each financial assetican no longer be described by a single value. It can only be described by its buying and selling values with respect to the other assets. These values are modeled as an adaptedcàdlàg3 d-dimensional matrix valued processΠ = (πi j)1i,jd, on some complete probability space(Ω,F,P) endowed with a filtrationF:= (Ft)tT

satisfying the usual assumptions. Each entry πi jt denotes the number of units of asset i which is required to obtain one unit of asset j at time t. They are assumed to satisfy the following natural conditions:

(i) πii t =1,π

i j

t >0 for alltT and 1≤i,jd P−a.s.

(ii) πi jtπikt πk jt for alltT and 1≤i,j,kd P−a.s.

The first condition has a clear interpretation: relative prices are positive. The second one means that it is always cheaper to directly exchange some units ofiagainst units of j rather than first convert units of i into units of k and then exchange these units of k against units of j. One can actually always reduce to this case as explained in[23, Section 1].

In this framework, a position Vbt at time t is said to be solvent if an immediate exchange in the market allows to turn it into a vector with non-negative components. In mathematical terms, this means that it belongs to the closed convex coneKbt(ω)generated by the vectorsei andπi jt (ω)eiej, 1≤i,jd, with(ei)1id the canonical basis ofRd, i.e., under the above conditions (i)-(ii):

b

Kt(ω):=

  ˆv∈R

d : aˆ

Md+s.t.ˆvi+

d X

j=1

ˆ

ajiaˆi jπi jt(ω)

≥0 ∀id

 

 , (1.2)

whereM+d denotes the set ofd-dimensional square matrices with non-negative entries. In the above equation ˆaji should be interpreted as the number of units of the asset i which are obtained by exchangingˆajiπtji units of the asset j.

In this model, the term “larger” used above thus meansVbtCbtKbt for alltT P−a.s. (in short b

V Cb).

It remains to specify the dynamic of portfolio processes. This is done by noting that an immediate transaction on the market changes the portfolio by a vector of quantities of the form ξt(ω) ∈ −∂Kbt(ω), the boundary of −Kbt(ω). The terms aˆi jt (ω) such that ξit(ω) =

Pd j=1

ˆ

atji(ω)−ˆai jt (ω)πi jt(ω) for id correspond to each transaction: one exchanges

ˆ

ai jt (ω)πi jt (ω)units ofiagainstˆai jt(ω)units of j. It is thus natural to defineself-financing strategies as vector processesVbsuch thatdVbt(ω)belongs in some sense to−Kbt(ω), the passage from−bKt(ω) to−Kbt(ω)reflecting the idea that one can always “throw away”, or consume, some (non-negative)

quantities of assets.

(4)

Such a modeling was introduced and studied at different levels of generality in [12], [13] and

[5]among others, and it is now known from the work of [22]and [5]that a good definition of self-financing wealth processes is the following:

Definition 1.1. We say that aRd-valuedlàdlàg4 predictable processV is ab self-financing strategyif it hasP−a.s. finite total variation and:

(i) ˙Vbc:=dVbc/dVar(Vbc)∈ −K db Var(Vbc)⊗P-a.e. , whereVbc denotes the continuous part of V andb Var(Vbc)its total variation,

(ii) ∆+Vbτ:=Vbτ+Vbτ∈ −KbτP−a.s. for all stopping timesτT ,

(iii) ∆Vbτ:=VbτVbτ−∈ −Kbτ−P−a.s. for all predictable stopping timesτT .

Given v∈Rd, we denote byVbvthe set of self-financing strategiesV such thatb Vb 0=v.

The setCbv is then naturally defined as the set of optionallàdlàg processesCbsuch thatVbCb.

A dual description of Cbv has already been obtained in discrete time models by [6]and [3], and extended to continuous time models in the very recent paper[9]5. The argument used in [9] is based on a discrete time approximation of the super-hedging problem, completed by a passage to the limit. However, this technique requires some regularity and only allows to consider the case whereCbiscàdlàg. In particular, it does not apply toself-financing strategieswhich are, in general, onlylàdlàg, see Section 2.3 below for more comments.

In the present paper, we use a totally different approach which allows to consider optionallàdlàg processes. It is based on a strong duality argument on the setS1(Q)of optional làdlàg processes

X such thatkXkS1(Q) := EQ ”

suptTkXt< ∞, for some well chosen P-equivalent probability measureQ. Namely, we show that Cb0∩ S1(Q)is closed inS1(Q) for someQ∼P. We then use a Hahn-Banach type argument together with a version of the well-known result of Meyer[21], see Proposition 2.1 below, that provides a representation of continuous linear form onS1(Q)in terms

of random measures.

For technical reasons, see[5], we shall assume all over this paper thatFT =FT andΠT= ΠT

P−a.s. Note however, that we can always reduce to this case by considering a larger time horizon T>T and by considering an auxiliary model whereFt=FT∗ andΠt= ΠT∗P−a.s. fort∈[T,T∗].

We shall also need the following:

Standing assumption: There exists at least onecàdlàgmartingaleZsuch that

(i) ZtKbt∗for alltT,P−a.s.

(ii) for every[0,T]∪ {∞}-valued stopping times ∈Int(Kbτ∗)P−a.s. on{τ <∞}

(iii) for every predictable[0,T]∪ {∞}-valued stopping timesZτ−∈Int(Kbτ−∗ )P−a.s. on{τ <∞}.

4The French acronymlàdlàg,limité à droite limité à gauche, means “with right and left limits”.

5We received this paper while preparing this manuscript. We are grateful to the authors for discussions we had on the

(5)

Here, Kbt∗(ω) := {y ∈Rd : Pidxiyi ≥ 0 ∀ xKbt(ω)} is the positive polar of Kbt(ω). In the following, we shall denote by Zs the set of processes satisfying the above conditions. We refer to

[5]and[23]for a discussion on the link between the existence of these so-calledstrictly consistent price processesand the absence of arbitrage opportunities, see also Section 3.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we first state an abstract version of our main duality result in terms of a suitable setD of dual processes. We then provide a more precise description of the setD which allows us to state our duality result in a form which is more in the spirit of [9, Theorem 4.2]. In Section 3, we also discuss this result in the light of the literature on optimal stopping and American options pricing in frictionless markets. Section 4 presents the extension of Meyer’s result. In Section 5, we prove the super-hedging theorem using the strong duality approach explained above.

Notations:From now on, we shall use the notation x y to denote the natural scalar product onRd. For a làdlàg optional process X, we define kXk := suptTkXtk. Given a process with bounded

variationsA, we writeAcand to denote its continuous and purely discontinuous parts, and by ˙A its density with respect to the associated total variation process Var(A):= (Vart(A))tT. The integral with respect toAhas to be understood as the sum of the integrals with respect toAcand. Given a làdlàg measurable processX on[0,T], we shall always use the conventionsXT+=XT andX0−=0.

2

Main results

2.1

Abstract formulation

Our dual formulation is based on the representation of continuous linear form onS1(Q)in terms

of elements of the setR ofR3d-valued adaptedcàdlàgprocessesA:= (A−,A◦,A+)withP-integrable total variation such that:

(i) A− is predictable,

(ii) A+ andA− are pure jump processes,

(iii) A0 =0 andA+T =A+T.

LettingS∞ denote the collection of elements ofS1(Q) with essentially bounded supremum, we

have:

Proposition 2.1. Fix Q ∼ P and let µ be a continuous linear form on S1(Q). Then, there exists A:= (A−,A◦,A+)∈ R such that:

µ(X) = (X|A]:=E  

Z T

0

XtdAt +

Z T

0

Xt dAt+

Z T

0

Xt+dA+t

 , ∀X ∈ S∞.

Note that such a result is known from[1]or[21]in the case ofcàdlàgorlàdcàg6processes, the one dimensionallàdlàg case being mentioned in[10]. A complete proof will be provided in Section 4 below.

(6)

To obtain the required dual formulation ofCb0, we then consider a particular subsetD ⊂ Rof dual processes that takes into account the special structure ofCb0:

Definition 2.1. LetDdenote the set of elements A∈ R such that

(C1)(Cb|A]≤0, for allCb∈ S∞satisfying0C.b

(C2)(Vb|A]≤0, for allVb∈Vb0with essentially bounded total variation.

A more precise description of the set D will be given in Lemma 2.1 and Lemma 2.2 below. In particular, it will enable us to extend the linear form(·|A], withA∈ D, to elements ofCbb0:=Cb0∩Sb

whereSbdenotes the set oflàdlàg optional processesX satisfyingX afor somea∈Rd.

This extension combined with a Hahn-Banach type argument, based on the key closure property of Proposition 5.1 below, leads to a natural polarity relation betweenD andCbb0. Here, given a subset EofSb, we define its polar as

E⋄:={A∈ R : (X|A]≤0 for allXE} ,

and define similarly the polar of a subsetF ofR as

F⋄:=X ∈ Sb : (X|A]≤0 for allAF ,

where we use the convention (X|A] = ∞ whenever R0TXtdAt + RT

0XtdA

t + RT

0Xt+dA +

t is not P

-integrable.

Our main result reads as follows:

Theorem 2.1. D⋄=Cb0

b and(Cb 0 b)

=D.

The first statement provides a dual formulation for the setCbb0of super-hedgeable American claims that are “bounded from below”. The second statement shows thatDis actually exactly the polar of

b C0

b for the relation defined above.

Remark 2.1. GivenCb∈ Sb, letΓ(Cb)denote the set of initial portfolio holdingsv such thatCb∈Cbv.

It follows from the above theorem and the identityCbv=v+Cb0that

Γ(Cb) =¦v∈Rd : (Cb−v|A]≤0 for allA∈ D© .

If the asset one is chosen as anuméraire, then the correspondingsuper-hedging priceis given by

p(Cb):=inf¦v1∈R : (v1, 0,· · ·, 0)∈Γ(Cb)© .

We shall continue this discussion in Remark 2.2 below.

2.2

Description of the set of dual processes

D

In this section, we provide a more precise description of the set of dual processesD. The proofs of the above technical results are postponed to the Appendix.

(7)

Lemma 2.1. Fix A:= (A−,A◦,A+)∈ R. Then(C1)holds if and only if

(i) ˙A−∈KbdVar(A−)⊗P-a.e.,

(ii) ˙AcKbdVar(Ac)P-a.e. andA˙◦δKbdVar(A◦δ)P-a.e.,

(iii) ˙A+KbdVar(A+)P-a.e.

In the following, we shall denote byRˆK the subset of elementsA∈ Rsatisfying the above conditions (i)-(iii).

We now discuss the implications of the constraint(C2). From now on, givenA:= (A−,A◦,A+)∈ R, we shall denote by ¯A− (resp. ¯A+) the predictable projection (resp. optional) of (δAt)tT (resp.

A+t)tT), whereδAt :=ATAt +ATAt+A+TA+tandδA+t :=ATAt +ATAt+A+TA+t.

Lemma 2.2. Fix A:= (A−,A◦,A+)∈ R. Then(C2)holds if and only if

(i) ¯AτKbτ−∗ P−a.s. for all predictable stopping timesτT ,

(ii) ¯A+τKbτ∗P−a.s. for all stopping timesτT .

In the following, we shall denote byR∆ ˆK the subset of elementsA∈ R satisfying the above condi-tions (i)-(ii).

Note that combining the above Lemmas leads to the following precise description ofD:

Corollary 2.1. D=RˆK∩ R∆ ˆK.

Remark 2.2. SinceKb⊃[0,∞)d, recall (1.2), it follows thatKb∗⊂[0,∞)d. The fact thatπi jteiej∈ b

Kt andπi jt >0 for all i,jd thus implies that y1=0⇒ y =0 for all yKb∗t(ω). It then follows from Lemma 2.1 that forA∈ D,(e1|A]≥0 and(e1|A] =0⇒(X|A] =0 for all X ∈ Sb. In view of

Remark 2.1, this shows that

p(Cb) = sup

B∈D1

(Cb|B] for allCb∈ Sb,

whereD1:={B=A/(e1,A], A∈ Ds.t.(e1,A]>0} ∪ {0}.

2.3

Alternative formulation

The dual formulation of Theorem 2.1 is very close to the one obtained in [3, Theorem 2.1], for discrete time models, and more recently in [9, Theorem 4.2], for càdlàg processes in continuous time models. Their formulation is of the form: ifCba for somea∈Rd, then

b

C∈Cbv ⇐⇒ sup

A◦∈D˜ E

 

Z T

0

(Cbtv)dAt

≤0 , (2.1)

where ˜Dis a family ofcàdlàgadapted processesA◦with integrable total variation such that

1.A0=0

2. There is a deterministic finite non-negative measureν◦on[0,T]and an adapted processZ◦such thatZ◦∈Kb∗P⊗ν◦-a.e.,A◦=R·

0Z

(8)

3. The optional projection ¯A◦of(ATAt)tT satisfies ¯AtKb∗t for alltT P−a.s.

In this section, we show that a similar representation holds in our framework. Namely, letN denote the set of triplets of non-negative random measuresν:= (ν−,ν◦,ν+)such thatν−is predictable,ν◦ andν+are optional and(ν−+ν◦+ν+)([0,T]) =1P−a.s.

Note thatν is usually called a randomized quasi-stopping time, and a randomized stopping time if ν+=ν−=0.

Remark 2.3. It follows from Remark 2.2 and Corollary 2.2 that, for Cb∈ Sb,

p(Cb) = sup

The proof of the above Corollary is an immediate consequence of Theorem 2.1 and the following representation result. belongs toD. We now prove the converse assertion.

(9)

2. We can then always assume that ¯ν :=ν−+ν◦+ν+ satisfies ¯ν([0,T])≤1P−a.s. Indeed, let f be some strictly increasing function mapping[0,∞)into [0, 1/3). Then, for i ∈ {−,◦,+}, νi is absolutely continuous with respect to ˜νi:= fi)and thus admits a density. Replacingνi by ˜νi and

multiplyingZi by the optional (resp. predictable) projection of the associated density leads to the required representation fori∈ {◦,+}(resp.i=−).

3.Finally, we can reduce to the case where ¯ν([0,T]) =1P−a.s. Indeed, sinceν−is only supported by graphs of[0,T]-valued random variables (recall thatA− is a pure jump process), we know that it has no continuous part at{T}. We can thus replaceν−by ˜ν−:=ν−+δ{T}(1−ν¯([0,T]))where δ{T} denotes the Dirac mass atT. We then also replace Z−by

˜

Z−:=Z−[1{t<T}+1{t=T}1{ν¯([0,T])<1}ν−({T})(ν−({T}) +1−ν¯([0,T]))−1]

so thatA−=R·

0Z˜

t ν˜

(d t). Observe that the assumptionF

T−=FT ensures that ˜ν−and ˜Z−are still

predictable. ƒ

Remark 2.4. Note that only the measure ν◦ appears in the formulation (2.1) and that it is de-terministic. In this sense our result is less tractable than the one obtained in [9] for continuous time models. However, as already pointed out in the introduction, the latter applies only tocàdlàg processes.

The reason for this it that their approach relies on a discrete time approximation of the super-hedging problem. Namely, they first prove that the result holds if we only imposeVbtCbtKbt on

a finite number of times tT, and then pass to the limit. Not surprisingly, this argument requires some regularity.

At first glance, this restriction may not seem important, but, it actually does not apply to admissible self-financing portfolios of the setVbv, since they are only assumed to belàdlàg (except whenΠis

continuous in which case the portfolios can be taken to be continuous, see the final discussion in

[9]).

3

Comparison with frictionless markets

Let us first recall that the frictionless market case corresponds to the situation where selling and buying is done at the same price, i.e. πi j = 1/πji for all i,jd. In this case, the price process (say in terms of the first asset) is Si := π1i and is a càdlàgsemimartingale, see [7]. In order to

avoid technicalities, it is usually assumed to be locally bounded. The no-arbitrage condition, more precisely no free lunch with vanishing risk, implies that the setM of equivalent measuresQunder which S = (Si)id is a local martingale is non-empty. Such measures should be compared to the strictly consistent price processesZofZs. Indeed, ifHdenotes the density process associated toQ, thenHSis “essentially” an element ofZs, and conversely, up to an obvious normalization. The term “essentially” is used here because in this case the interior ofKb∗ is empty and the notion of interior has to be replaced by that of relative interior. See the comments in[23, Section 1].

As already explained in the introduction, in such models, the wealth process can be simply repre-sented by its valueV =SVb. The main difference is that the set of admissible strategies is no more described byVb0but in terms of stochastic integrals with respect toS.

(10)

the Snell envelope of C computed under Q, see e.g. [18]and the references therein. Equivalently, the American claimCbcan be super-hedged from a zero initial endowment if and only if theQ-Snell envelope ofC at time 0 is non-positive.

In the case where C islàdlàg and of class (D), theQ-Snell envelopeJQ ofC satisfies, see[10, p. 135]and[11, Proposition 1],

J0Q = sup τ∈T

EQCτ= sup

(τ,τ,τ+)

EQCτ+Cτ◦+Cτ++ (3.1)

whereT is the set of all[0,T]-valued stopping times, ˜T is the set quasi-stopping times, i.e. the set of triplets of[0,T]∪ {∞}-valued stopping times(τ−,τ◦,τ+) such thatτ− is predictable and, a.s., only one of them is finite. Here, we use the conventionC∞−=C∞=C∞+=0. The first formulation

is simple but does not allow to provide an existence result, while the second does. Indeed, [11, Proposition 1],

J0Q = EQCτ−ˆ 1lB−+Cτˆ1lB◦+Cτˆ+1lB+

where

ˆ

τ:=inf{t∈[0,T] : JQt=Ct−orJtQ=Ct orJt+Q =Ct+}

and

B−:={JtQ=Ct−}, B◦:={JtQ=Ct} ∩(B−)c, B+:= (B−∪B◦)c.

It thus suffices to setτˆi:= ˆτ1lBi +∞1l(Bi)c fori∈ {−,◦,+}to obtain

J0Q=EQˆ−+Cτˆ◦+Cτˆ++ .

This shows that, in general, one needs to consider quasi stopping times instead of stopping times if one wants to establish an existence result, see also [1, Proposition 1.2] for the case of càdlàg processes.

In the case of incomplete markets, the super-hedging price is given by the supremum over allQ∈ M

ofJ0Q,[18, Theorem 3.3]. See also[14]for the case of portfolio constraints.

In our framework, the measure ν ∈ N that appears in (2.2) can be interpreted as a randomized version of the quasi-stopping times while the result of[9], of the form (2.1), should be interpreted as a formulation in terms of randomized stopping times, recall the definitions given in Section 2.3 after the introduction of N as well as Remark 2.3. Both are consistent with the results of [3]

and [6] that show that the duality does not work in discrete time models if we restrict to (non-randomized) stopping times. In both cases the process ZZ˜(ν)plays the role ofHQS where HQ

is the density process associated to the equivalent martingale measuresQmentioned above. These two formulations thus correspond to the two representations of the Snell envelope in (3.1). As in frictionless markets, the formulation of [9]is simpler while ours should allow to find the optimal randomized quasi-stopping time, at least whenZ is fixed. We leave this point for further research.

4

On continuous linear forms for

làdlàg

processes

(11)

4.1

Extension of Meyer’s result

We first state a version of Theorem 27 in Chapter VI in[21]for the set ˜S∞oflàdlàg B([0,T])⊗F -measurableP-essentially bounded processes.

Theorem 4.1. Letµ˜be a linear form onS˜∞such that:

(A1) ˜µ(Xn)→0for all sequence(Xn)n0of positive elements of S˜∞such thatsupnkXnkS˜∞≤M for

some M>0and satisfyingkXnk∗→0P-a.s.

Then, there exists three measuresαandα+ on[0,T]×Ωsuch that

1. α is carried by (0,T]×Ω and by a countable union of graphs of [0,T]-valued F-measurable random variables.

2. α+ is carried by [0,T)×Ω and by a countable union of graphs of [0,T]-valued F-measurable random variables.

3. α = αδ +αc

where α δ

is carried by [0,T]×Ω and by a countable union of graphs of [0,T] -valuedF-measurable random variables,αcis carried by [0,T]×Ωand does not charge any graph of [0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variable.

4. For all X ∈S˜∞, we have

˜ µ(X) =

Z

Ω Z T

0

Xt(ω)α(d t,dω) +

Z

Ω Z T

0

Xt(ω)α(d t,dω) +

Z

Ω Z T

0

Xt+(ω)α+(d t,dω).

This decomposition is unique among the set of measures satisfying the above conditions 1., 2. and 3.

The proof can be decomposed in four main steps:

Step 1. To a processX in ˜S∞, we associate

¯

X(t,ω,−):=Xt−(ω), ¯X(t,ω,◦):=Xt and ¯X(t,ω,+):=Xt+(ω),

so as to keep track of the right and left limits and isolate the point-value. Note that ¯X is a measurable map on

W := ((0,T]×Ω× {−})∪([0,T]×Ω× {◦})∪([0,T)×Ω× {+})

endowed with the sigma-algebraW :=σ(X¯, ¯X∈S¯∞), where ¯S∞:={X¯|X ∈S˜∞}.

Step 2.Since ¯S∞is a lattice andX7→X¯is a bijection, we next observe that a linear form ˜µon ˜S∞

can always be associated to a linear form ¯µon ¯S∞by ¯µ(X¯):=µ(˜ X).

Step 3.We then deduce from the above condition (A1) that Daniell’s condition holds for ¯µ, see e.g.

[17]. This allows to construct a signed bounded measure ¯ν on (W,W) such that ˜µ(X) =µ(¯ X¯) = ¯

ν(X¯).

Step 4. The rest of the proof consists in identifying the triplet(α,α,α+)of Theorem 4.1 in terms of ¯ν defined on(W,W).

It is clear that we can always reduce to the one dimensional case since ˜µis linear. From now on, we shall therefore only consider the cased=1. We decompose the proof in different Lemmata.

(12)

Lemma 4.1. Assume that(A1)holds. Then, there exists a signed bounded measureν¯on(W,W)such thatµ(˜ X) =µ(¯ X¯) =ν¯(X¯)and|µ˜|(X) =|µ¯|(X¯) =|ν¯|(X¯)for all X∈S˜∞.

Proof. We first assume that the linear form ˜µis non-negative. We only have to prove that ¯µsatisfies the Daniell’s condition:

(A2) If(X¯n)n≥0 decreases to zero then ¯µ(X¯n)→0.

Let (X¯n)n0 be a sequence of non-negative elements ofS¯∞ that decreases to 0. For ε > 0, we introduce the sets

An(ω):={t∈[0,T]|Xnt+(ω)≥εor Xtn(ω)≥ε},

Bn(ω):={t∈[0,T]|Xnt(ω)≥ε},

Kn(ω):=An(ω)∪Bn(ω). (4.1)

Obviously, Kn+1(ω) ⊂ Kn(ω), T

n≥0Kn(ω) =;and An(ω) is closed. Let (tk)k≥1 be a sequence of

Kn(ω)converging tos∈[0,T]. If there is a subsequence(tφ(k))k1 such thatXtφ(

k) ∈An(ω)for all

k≥0, thensKn(ω), sinceAn(ω)is closed. If not, we can suppose thantkbelongs toBn(ω)for all k≥1, after possibly passing to a subsequence. Since X(ω)islàdlàg and bounded, we can extract a subsequence((k))k≥1such that limXtφ(k)(ω)∈ {Xs−(ω),Xs(ω),Xs+(ω)}. SinceXtφ(k)(ω)≥ε, we

deduce thatsKn(ω). This proves thatKn(ω)is closed. Using the compactness of[0,T], we then obtain that there exists someNε>0 for which ∪nNεKn(ω) =;. Thus, kX

n(ω)k

< εforn. Since ˜µsatisfies (A1), this implies that ¯µsatisfies Daniell’s condition (A2).

To cover the case where ˜µis not non-negative and prove the last assertion of the Theorem, we can follow exactly the same arguments as in[21, Chapter VI]. We first use the standard decomposition argument ˜µ=µ˜+−µ˜−where ˜µ+and ˜µ−are non-negative and satisfy (A1). This allows to construct two signed measures ¯ν+ and ¯ν− on (W,W) such that ¯µ+ =ν¯+, ¯µ−= ν¯− and therefore ¯µ=ν¯ := ¯

ν+−ν¯−. Finally, we observe that, for non-negative X, |µ˜|(X) = sup{µ(˜ Y), YS˜∞,|Y| ≤ X} =

|µ¯|(X¯) =sup{µ(¯ Y¯), ¯YS¯∞,|Y¯| ≤X¯}=|ν¯|(X¯) =sup{ν¯(Y¯), ¯YS¯∞,|Y¯| ≤X¯}, and recall thatW is

generated by ¯S∞. ƒ

To conclude the proof, it remains to identify the triplet(α−,α◦,α+) of Theorem 4.1 in terms of ¯ν

defined on(W,W). This is based on the two following Lemmas.

From now on, to a functionc on [0,T]×Ω we associate the three functionsc−, c◦ andc+ defined

onW by

c−(t,w,+) =c−(t,ω,◦) =0 and c−(t,ω,−) =c(t,ω), c(t,w,+) =c(t,ω,−) =0 and c(t,ω,◦) =c(t,ω),

c+(t,w,−) =c+(t,ω,◦) =0 and c+(t,ω,+) =c(t,ω).

Lemma 4.2. If S is a F-measurable [0,T]-valued random variable, then [[S]]+,[[S]] and [[S]] belongs toW.

Proof. For ε > 0, we set := 1]]S,(S+ε)∧T[[ which belongs to S˜∞. The associated process ¯

is the indicator function of the set :=]]S,(S+ε)T]]∪]]S,(S+ε)T[[∪[[S,(S+ε)T[[+ which belongs toW. Taking εn :=1/nwith n≥ 1, we thus obtain∩n1Iεn = [[S]]

+∈ W. Using

(13)

1[[S,(S+ε)T[[, we also obtain that[[S]]+∪[[S]]∈ W. Since[[S]]= ([[S]]+∪[[S]])∩([[S]]+)c,

this shows that[[S]]∈ W. ƒ

Similarly, given a subsetC of[0,T]×Ω, we set

C−={(t,ω,−)∈W |(t,ω)C, t>0}

C◦={(t,ω,◦)∈W |(t,ω)C}

C+={(t,ω,+)∈W |(t,ω)C, t<T}.

Lemma 4.3. If C is a measurable set of[0,T]×Ω, then C+∪C◦∪C−∈ W.

Proof. SinceB([0,T])⊗ F is generated by continuous measurable processes, it suffices to check thatX+X+X+isW-measurable wheneverX is continuous and measurable. This is obvious since

¯

X =X−+X◦+X+in this case. ƒ

We can now conclude the proof of Theorem 4.1.

Proof of Theorem 4.1. We first defineH as the collection of sets of the formA=Sn0[[Sn]]+ for a given sequence(Sn)n0 of[0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variables. This set is closed under countable union. The quantity supA∈H |ν¯|(A) =:M is well defined since ¯ν is bounded. Let(An)n≥1

be a sequence such that lim|ν¯|(An) =M and setG+:= S

n≥0An, so that|ν¯|(G+) =M. Observe that

we can easily reduce to the case where the G+ is the union of disjoint graphs. We then define the measure ¯ν+:=ν¯(· ∩G+)and, recall Lemma 4.3,

α+(C):=ν¯+(C+∪C−∪C◦) =ν¯+(C+)

forC ∈ B([0,T])⊗F. The measureα+is carried by graphs of[0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variable. Moreover, for all[0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variableS, we have

α+([[S]]) =ν¯([[S]]+).

Indeed, ¯ν([[S]]+)> ν([[¯ S]]+G+) implies ¯ν([[S]]+G+)> ν(¯ G+), which contradicts the maxi-mality ofG+.

We constructG−, G◦ and the measures α− and ¯ν− similarly. The measure ¯νδ is defined by ¯νδ := ¯

ν(.∩G)and the measureαδbyαδ(C):=ν¯δ(C+CC), forC ∈ B([0,T])⊗ F.

We then set ¯νc

◦:=ν¯−ν¯+−ν¯−−ν¯◦δand defineαc◦byαc(C):=ν¯◦c(C+∪C◦∪C−)forC∈ B([0,T])×F, recall Lemma 4.3 again. Observe that ¯νδ, ¯νc and ¯ν−do not charge any element of the form[[S]]+

withS a[0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variable. This follows from the maximal property of G+. Similarly, ¯νc, ¯ν

δ

◦ and ¯ν+ do not charge any element of the form [[S]]− and ¯νc, ¯ν− and ¯ν+ do

not charge any element of the form[[S]]◦.

We now fixX ∈S˜∞ and setu: (t,ω) 7→Xt−(ω), v :(t,ω)7→ Xt(ω)and w :(t,ω)7→ Xt+(ω).

Then, ¯X=u+v+w+ and, by Lemma 4.1,

˜

µ(X) =ν¯(X¯) = (ν¯+ν¯δ+ν¯c+ν¯+)(u−+v◦+w+).

Since ¯ν− is carried by G−, ¯ν+ by G+, ¯νδ by G◦ and ¯νc does not charge any graph of [0,T]-valued

F-measurable random variable, we deduce that

¯

(14)

where the last equality comes from the definition ofα+andw. Similarly, we have

¯

ν−(u−+v◦+w+) =ν¯−(u−) =α−(u),

¯

νδ(u+v+w+) =ν¯δ(v) =αδ(v).

Sinceu,vandwdiffer only on a countable union of graphs, it also follows that ¯νc(u−+v◦+w+) =

¯

νc(v) =αc(v). Hence

µ(X) =α(u) +αc(v) +αδ(v) +α+(w)

which is assertion 3. of the Theorem withα:=αc+αδ.

To prove the uniqueness of the decomposition, it suffices to show that for a measure ˜µsatisfying 1, 2 and 3 of Theorem 4.1 then ˜µ=0 impliesα=α+=α=0. This follows from similar arguments as the one used in the proof of Lemma 2.1 above. One first proves thatα=α+=0, using the fact that they are carried by a countable union of graphs of[0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variables. For α+, the result is obtained by considering processes ,S,ε of the form ,S,ε := ξ1(S,(S+ε)T), whereSis a[0,T]-valuedF-measurable random variable,ξa realF-measurable random variable, andε >0, and lettingεgoing to 0. Forα, the result is obtained by considering processes,S,ε of the form,S,ε:=ξ1(0(S−ε),S). The result forαfollows then from standard arguments. ƒ

4.2

Proof of Proposition 2.1

We finally provide the proof of Proposition 2.1.

Proof. Observe that S1(Q) is closed in the set S˜1(Q) of all làdlàg B([0,T])⊗ F-measurable processes X satisfyingEQ[kXk]<∞. Using the Hahn-Banach theorem, we can find an extension ˜

µofµdefined on ˜S1(Q), i.e. ˜µ(X) =µ(X)forX ∈ S1(Q). Obviously, ˜µsatisfies condition (A1) of Theorem 4.1. Thus it satisfies the representation of Theorem 4.1, and so doesµonS∞.

Sinceµ(X) =0 for alllàdlàg processesX such thatX =0Q-a.s., the measuresα,αandα+admit Radon-Nykodim densities with respect toP∼Q. We can thus find threeRd-valued processes ˜A−, ˜A◦ and ˜A+with essentially bounded total variation satisfying forX∈ S∞:

µ(X) =E  

Z T

0

XtdA˜−t + Z T

0

XtdA˜◦t+

Z T

0

Xt+dA˜+   ,

with ˜A0 =0 and ˜A+T =A˜+T, ˜A+ and ˜A− are pure jump processes. To conclude, it suffices to replace ˜

A− by its dual predictable projection A−, and ˜A◦, ˜A+ by their dual optional projections A◦ andA+. One can always add the continuous parts ofA−andA+toA◦to reduce to the case whereA−andA+

coincide with pure jumps processes. ƒ

5

The strong duality approach

(15)

5.1

The closure property

The proof of Theorem 2.1 is based on a Hahn-Banach type argument and the following key clo-sure property which is obtained by considering a probability meaclo-sure QZ defined by dQZ/dP := cZ1PidZTi with cZ :=E”PidZTi—, for some element Z ofZs. In the following Proposition, we also state a Fatou type closure property which will also be used in the proof of Theorem 2.1 in order to approximate elements ofSbby processes with essentially bounded supremum.

Proposition 5.1. (i)For all Z∈ Zs,Cb0∩ S1(QZ)is closed inS1(QZ).

(ii)Let a∈Rd and let(Cbn)n1 be a sequence inCb0 such thatCbna for all n≥1andkCbnCbk→0 in probability for somelàdlàg optional processC with values inb Rd. Then,Cb∈Cb0.

Note that the last assertion is an immediate consequence of Lemma 8, Lemma 12 and Proposition 14 of[5], see also the proof of their Theorem 15. It is rather standard in this literature. However, the closure property inS1(QZ)is new and does not seem to have been exploited so far.

In order to prove Proposition 5.1, we start with an easy Lemma which essentially follows from arguments used in the proof of Lemma 8 in[5].

Lemma 5.1. Fix Cb∈Cb0∩ S1(QZ)for some Z ∈ Zs and Vb ∈Vb0 such thatVb C. Then, Zb V is ab supermartingale. Moreover,

E  

Z T

0

ZsVscdVars(Vbc) +X

sT

ZsVbs+X

s<T

Zs∆+Vbs

≥E”ZTVbT— .

Proof. SinceZtKbt∗andVbtCbtKbt for alltT P−a.s., it follows thatZtVbtZtCbt for alltT

P−a.s. and therefore, by the martingale property ofZ,

ZtVbt ≥E”ZTCbt | Ft—≥ −E –

kZTk sup

s∈[0,T]

kCbsk | Ft ™

for alltT P−a.s. (5.1)

SinceCb∈ S1(Q

Z), the right-hand side term is a martingale. Moreover, a direct application of the

integration by parts formula yields

ZtVbt = Z t

0 b

Vsd Zs+ Z t

0

ZsVscdVars(Vbc) + X

st

Zs−∆Vbs+ X

s<t

Zs∆+Vbs.

We now observe that the definitions of Zs and Vb0 imply that the three last integrals on the right-hand side are equal to non-increasing processes. In view of (5.1), this implies that the local martingale (Rt

0Vbsd Zs)tT is bounded from below by a martingale and is therefore a

super-martingale. Similarly,ZVb is a local super-martingale which is bounded from below by a martingale and is therefore a super-martingale. The proof is concluded by taking the expectation in both sides

of the previous inequality applied tot=T. ƒ

To complete the proof, we shall appeal to the following alternative representation of the set Vb0

(16)

Proposition 5.2. LetV be ab Rd-valued predictable process withP-a.s. finite total variation such that

where conv denotes the closure inRd of the convex envelope.

Proof of Proposition 5.1. As already mentioned, the last assertion is an immediate consequence of Lemma 8, Lemma 12 and Proposition 14 of [5], see also the proof of their Theorem 15. We now prove the first one which is obtained by very similar arguments. Let(Cbn)n1 be a sequence in

b

SinceCbTnconverges toCbT inL1(QZ), the right-hand side of the latter inequality is uniformly bounded and so is the quantityEQ˜Z”Var

T(Vbn) —

. It thus follows from Proposition 14 in[5]that, after possibly passing to convex combinations, we can assume that,P−a.s.,(Vbn)n1converges pointwise on[0,T] to a predictable processVbwith finite variations. The pointwise convergence ensures thatVbCb. By Proposition 5.2,Vbn satisfies (5.2) for alln≥1, and it follows from the pointwise convergence that

b

V satisfies (5.2) too. We can then conclude from Proposition 5.2 thatVb∈Vb0. ƒ

5.2

Proof of Theorem 2.1

We can now prove the super-hedging Theorem. We split the proof in several Propositions.

(17)

Thus, it suffices to show that

ForVbwith an essentially bounded total variation, this is a direct consequence of(C2)in the defini-tion ofD. In the general case, we observe thatVbCba∈Rd implies thatVbcan be approximated from below (in the sense of ) by the sequence (Vbn)n1 defined by Vbn := Vb1[[0,τn]]+a 1]]τn,T]]

where(τn)n1 is a localizing sequence of stopping times for Var(Vb), so thatτn↑ ∞. The existence of this sequence is justified by the fact that Var(Vb) is predictable and almost surely finite, thus locally bounded. Observe thatVbn∈Vb0 and has essentially bounded variation, we thus have

E uniformly in n, by an integrable random variable which depends only onAand a. Since VbnVb uniformly on compact sets,P−a.s., we can conclude by appealing to Fatou’s Lemma. ƒ

We now prove the converse implication. To this purpose, we shall appeal to our two key results: Proposition 5.1 and Proposition 2.1.

Proposition 5.4. Cbb0⊃ D⋄.

Proof. FixCb∈ D⋄such thatCba.

Step 1. We first consider the case where Cb∈ S∞. Assume that Cb does not belong to the convex coneCb0. Fix Z ∈ Zs and observe thatCb6∈Cb0∩ S1(QZ). The latter being closed inS1(QZ), see Proposition 5.1, it follows from the Hahn-Banach separation theorem that we can findµin the dual ofS1(QZ)such thatµ(X)≤c< µ(Cb)for allX ∈Cb0∩ S∞, for some realc. SinceCb0is a cone, it satisfies(C1). Since it also has to satisfy(C2), this implies thatA∈ D, which leads to a contradiction.

Step 2. We conclude the proof by considering the case where Cbis not bounded but only satisfies

b

(18)

Observing thatCbCbnfor alln≥1 and recalling thatCb∈ D⋄, we deduce from Lemma 2.1(D ⊂ RKb)

We now conclude the proof of Theorem 2.1.

Proposition 5.5. (Cb0

Proof of Lemma 2.1. We only prove that (i)-(iii) holds if(C1)is satisfied. The converse is obvious. Letξbe any bounded optionallàdlàg process such that−ξ0. GivenB∈ F, letλbe the optional projection of 1B. Note that it is càdlàg, since1B(ω) is constant for each ω, and that the process λ coincides with the predictable projection of1B, see Chapter V in[8]. We then set ˜ξ:=λξ. We remark that ˜ξis the optional projection of1, since ξis optional, and that ˜ξ− is the predictable projection of 1Bξ−, sinceξ− is predictable. Since the set valued process Kb is a cone and λ takes values in [0, 1], we have −ξ˜ 0. Moreover, since A− is predictable (resp. A◦,A+ are optional), it follows that the induced measure commutes with the predictable projection (resp. the optional projection), see e.g. Theorem 3 Chapter I in[21]. Applying(C1)to ˜ξthus implies that

0 ≥ E

By the arbitrariness ofB, this shows that thecàdlàgprocessX defined by

X:=

ǫ→0 shows thatX is non-decreasing (recall (iii) of the definition ofR). In particular, its continuous part is non-decreasing, see e.g. Chapter VII in[20]. SinceA−andA+are purely discontinuous, this implies that the continuous part ofR0·ξtdAt is non-decreasing. Letting Ac denote the continuous part ofA◦, we thus deduce that

(19)

We now replace ξ by ˜ξ := ξ1]]τ,τ

for all stopping times τ with values in [0,T]. Since the cone valued process Kb is generated by a family of càdlàg adapted processes, which we can always assume to be bounded, (A.1), (A.2), (A.3), (A.4) and (iii) of the definition ofRimply the required result. ƒ

The following prepares for the proof of Lemma 2.2.

Lemma A.1. LetV be an elementb Vb0with essentially bounded total variation. Then,

(Vb|A] =E

Proof. By Fubini’s theorem and the continuity ofVbc,

(20)

This shows hat

(A|V] = E 

X

tT

δAtVbt+

Z T

0

δA+t dVbtc+X

t<T

δA+t ∆+Vbt

  .

The proof is concluded by replacingδA−(resp.δA+) by its dual predictable (resp. optional) projec-tion, which is made possible by the special measurability of the variations ofVb, see Definition 1.1. ƒ

Proof of Lemma 2.2. First assume that(C2)holds. Then, it follows from Lemma A.1 that:

E 

X

tT

¯

AtVbt+

Z T

0

¯

A+t dVbtc+X

t<T

¯ A+t ∆+Vbt

≤0 , (A.5)

for allVb ∈Vb0∩ S∞ with essentially bounded total variation. It thus follows from Definition 1.1 that E”A¯−τξ—≤ 0 for all predicable stopping timesτT P−a.s. and bounded Fτ−-measurable ξtaking values in−Kbτ− P−a.s. Similarly,E

”

¯

A+τξ—≤0 for all stopping times τ < T P−a.s. and boundedFτ-measurableξtaking values in−KbτP−a.s. Observe that ¯A+T =0∈Kb

T since∆A + T =0.

Recalling the definition ofKb in terms of its generating family based onΠ, this implies that (i) and (ii) are satisfied. Conversely, ifAsatisfies (i) and (ii), then (A.5) holds for allVb∈Vb0with essentially bounded total variation and we deduce from Lemma A.1 that(C2)holds. ƒ

References

[1] Bismut J.-M. (1979). Temps d’arrêt optimal, quasi-temps d’arrêt et retournement du temps. Ann. Probab.7, 933-964. MR0548890

[2] Bouchard B. and H. Pham (2004). Wealth-Path Dependent Utility Maximization in Incom-plete Markets.Finance and Stochastics, 8 (4), 579-603. MR2212119

[3] Bouchard B. and E. Temam (2005). On the Hedging of American Options in Discrete Time Markets with Proportional Transaction Costs.Electronic Journal of Probability, 10, 746-760. MR2164029

[4] Bouchard B., N. Touzi and A. Zeghal (2004). Dual Formulation of the Utility Maximization Problem : the case of Nonsmooth Utility.The Annals of Applied Probability, 14 (2), 678-717. MR2052898

[5] Campi L. and W. Schachermayer (2006). A super-replication theorem in Kabanov’s model of transaction costs.Finance and Stochastics, 10(4), 579-596. MR2276320

[6] Chalasani P. and S. Jha (2001). Randomized stopping times and American option pricing with transaction costs.Mathematical Finance, 11(1), 33-77. MR1807848

[7] Delbaen F. and W. Shachermayer (1998). The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for unbounded stochastic processes.Math. Annalen,312, 215-250. MR1671792

(21)

[9] Denis E. , D. De Vallière and Y. Kabanov (2008). Hedging of american options under trans-action costs.preprint.

[10] El Karoui N. (1979). Les aspects probabilistes du contrôle stochastique.Ecole d’Eté de Prob-abilités de Saint FlourIX, Lecture Notes in Mathematics 876, Springer Verlag.

[11] El Karoui N. (1982). Une propriété de domination de l’enveloppe de Snell des semimartin-gales fortes.Sém. prob. Strasbourg, 16, 400-408.

[12] Kabanov Y. and G. Last (2002). Hedging under transaction costs in currency markets: a continuous time model.Mathematical Finance, 12, 63-70. MR1883786

[13] Kabanov Y. and C. Stricker (2002). Hedging of contingent claims under transaction costs. Advances in Finance and Stochastics. Eds. K. Sandmann and Ph. Sch¨onbucher, Springer, 125-136. MR1929375

[14] Karatzas I. and S. G. Kou (1998). Hedging American contingent claims with constrained portfolios.Finance and Stochastics, 2, 215-258. MR1809521

[15] Karatzas I. and S. E. Shreve (1991). Brownian motion and stochastic calculus. Springer Verlag, Berlin. MR1121940

[16] Karatzas I. et S.E. Shreve (1998), Methods of Mathematical Finance, Springer Verlag. MR1640352

[17] Kindler J. (1983). A simple proof of the Daniell-Stone representation theorem.Amer. Math. Monthly, 90 (3), 396-397. MR0707155

[18] Kramkov D. (1996). Optional decomposition of supermartingales and hedging in incomplete security markets.Probability Theory and Related Fields, 105 (4), 459-479. MR1402653

[19] Kramkov D. and W. Schachermayer (1999). The Asymptotic Elasticity of Utility Functions and Optimal Investment in Incomplete Markets. Annals of Applied Probability, 93, 904 -950. MR1722287

[20] Meyer P.A. (1966).Probabilités et potentiel. Hermann, Paris. MR0205287

[21] Meyer P.A. (1976). Un cours sur les intégrales stochastiques. Sém. prob. Strasbourg, 10, 245-400. MR0501332

[22] Rasonyi M. (2003). A remark on the superhedging theorem under transaction costs. Sémi-naire de Probabilités XXXVII, Lecture Notes in Math., 1832, Springer, Berlin-Heidelberg-New York, 394-398. MR2053056

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

Advertising Association (OAA). Dengan dukungan yang kuat membuat organisasi ini tidak hanya disegani di masyarakat melainkan dapat bekerja dengan hingga mencapai tujuan

Where-used / how-used – suatu daftar dari proses yang menggunakan data atau item control dan bagaimana dia digunakan (misalnya, input ke proses,. output dari proses, sebagai suatu

Berdasarkan hasil pengujian sistem yang telah dilakukan secara keseluruhan pada black box dengan kasus uji diatas dapat ditarik kesimpulan bahwa pembangunan

Berdasarkan analisis data dan obyek penelitian, maka dapat ditarik kesimpulan bahwa pertama, berdasarkan obyek penelitian, terdapat tiga karekter organisasi OPZ yaitu OPZ

Perusahaan dengan pengendalian internal yang lebih baik dalam bentuk keberadaan fungsi audit internal dan manajemen risiko akan mengurangi monitoring eksternal dari

Speech acts, which is technical term in linguistics, is the acts of communication which is usually used to make request, asking questions, giving orders,

Unit Layanan Pengadaan Kota Banjarbaru mengundang penyedia Pengadaan Barang/Jasa untuk mengikuti Pelelangan Umum pada Pemerintah Kota Banjarbaru yang dibiayai dengan Dana APBD

Untuk Jalan Arteri Primer Sudirman volume arus lalu lintas harian tertinggi terjadi pada hari Senin sebesar 2823,2 smp / jam, kapasitas (C) Jalan Arteri Primer Sudirman adalah