• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

00074910012331338973

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "00074910012331338973"

Copied!
3
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at

http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=cbie20

Download by: [Universitas Maritim Raja Ali Haji], [UNIVERSITAS MARITIM RAJA ALI HAJI

TANJUNGPINANG, KEPULAUAN RIAU] Date: 19 January 2016, At: 22:07

Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies

ISSN: 0007-4918 (Print) 1472-7234 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cbie20

“Indonesian Monetary Policy”: A Rejoinder

George Fane

To cite this article:

George Fane (2000) “Indonesian Monetary Policy”: A Rejoinder, Bulletin of

Indonesian Economic Studies, 36:3, 71-72

To link to this article:

http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00074910012331338973

Published online: 18 Aug 2006.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 31

View related articles

(2)

Vol 36 No 3, December 2000, pp. 71–2

Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies

‘INDONESIAN MONETARY POLICY’:

A REJOINDER

George Fane

Australian National University

My article in this issue (pp. 49–64) makes two main points. First, because changes in the velocity of base money were small relative to the huge expansion in its level, Grenville’s favoured policy of targeting domestic prices would have been similar to the IMF’s policy of targeting base money, while both would have been totally different from the actual policy in which base money was expanded by far more than was needed to accommodate the banking panic. Second, almost as soon as base money was kept to the announced targets, inflation was halted and the exchange rate appreciated.

Grenville never mentions either point. Instead he sets up a straw man by interpreting the policy of targeting base money to mean that it is rigidly kept to an announced day-to-day path, but that the banks continue to hold the minuscule reserves that are optimal for them under the quite different regime in which the central bank stands ready to provide whatever liquidity is needed each day to allow the banking system to clear at roughly unchanged interest rates. This implicit assumption of unchanged behaviour despite a radical change in the policy regime that conditions that behaviour is an excellent example of the fallacy exposed by the Lucas critique.

I accept Grenville’s criticism that I misquoted him on US monetary policy, but reject the significance that he attributes to my error, both because I did not advocate rigid day-to-day targeting of base money and because imposing rigid day-to-day base money targets would not lead to regular failures of the clearing system, but would rather force banks to hold increased deposits at the central bank. However, I do not believe that it is an optimal policy either, and I did not deal with it in my article, where I defended the policy of base money targeting in the way that it was proposed by the IMF for the Asian currency countries: quarterly

(3)

72 George Fane

and annual targets were announced, with the intention that monetary policy would be somewhat tightened, or loosened, depending on whether the latest observation on base money was above, or below, the target. Grenville argues that Korea and Thailand were not really targeting base money because, over the first 12 months of their plans, base money was scheduled to grow but actually fell. He says that this proves the impossibility of targeting base money—‘a target is not a ceiling’. Here again, he is adopting the rigid interpretation of base money targeting. He seems not to notice that his own preferred policy of targeting inflation could be reduced to absurdity by interpreting it to mean that monetary policy must be adjusted on a day-to-day basis to keep an index of domestic prices exactly to a rigid pre-announced path. In the crisis of confidence of 1997–98 it was much more important to reassure markets that there would not be an explosion of the money supply than to prevent it falling below the target. If Bank Indonesia had adopted Grenville’s advice and set a target of, say, 20% for annual inflation, and if prices had instead fallen slightly, it would be a severe critic who claimed that this ‘failure’ proved the impossibility of inflation targeting.

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

Glukosa dilarutkan dalam air diambil pada awal pengujian. Tingkat kadar glukosa darah rata-rata di mana glukosa ditemukan dalam sampel urin adalah sekitar 170 atau 180 mg / dl.

LAPORAN RESMI PRAKTIKUM FISIKA DASAR I.

Septiani dan Arkeman (2013) telah merancang model penanganan risiko transportasi pada agroindustri susu dengan pendekatan logika fuzzy, pada paper ini, tahapan identifikasi

_ Be.rqlsqrkll surat penetapan penyedia Barangruasa Nomor o27l-1.r,98 luL:pl2olg .rangg_al 02 April 2013, dengan ini Kelompok Ke a Unit Layanan psngadaan mengumumkan Hasil

2) Pada perhitungan prediksi data populasi ternak Sapi Propinsi NTT dengan metode pemulusan eksponensial tunggal atau single exponential smoothing didapat hasil RMSE

Dalam pendekatan ordinal, konsumen dengan pendapatan tertentu akan mengurangi penggunaan makanan anorganik dan mulai menambah konsumsi makanan organik, namun kepuasan dari

Berdasarkan data penelitian, penyebab interferensi yang ditemui dalam teks narasi SMA Negeri 3 Kota Sungai Penuh adalah pertama, adanya penyamaan berlebihan terhadap

Andri Hermanto,2014 STRATEGI PEMBELAJARAN MUHADATSAH DENGAN METODE SAM’IYAH SYAFAWIYAH Universitas Pendidikan Indonesia | repository.upi.edu | perpustakaan.upi.edu. ﺗ