• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

getdoc8e36. 195KB Jun 04 2011 12:04:40 AM

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "getdoc8e36. 195KB Jun 04 2011 12:04:40 AM"

Copied!
11
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

ELECTRONIC

COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY

AN EXPONENTIAL MARTINGALE EQUATION

MICHAEL MANIA

A. Razmadze Mathematical Institute, 1, M. Aleksidze St., Tbilisi, Georgia,

Georgian–American University, Business School, 3, Alleyway II, Chavchavadze Ave. 17 a, Tbilisi, Georgi

email: E-mail:mania@@rmi.acnet.ge

REVAZ TEVZADZE

Institute of Cybernetics, 5, S. Euli St., Tbilisi, Georgia

Georgian–American University, Business School, 3, Alleyway II, Chavchavadze Ave. 17 a, Tbilisi, Georgia

email: E-mail:tevza@@cybernet.ge

Submitted April 20 2006, accepted in final form September 5 2006 AMS 2000 Subject classification: 90A09, 60H30, 90C39.

Keywords: Backward stochastic differential equation, exponential martingale, martingale mea-sures.

Abstract

We prove an existence of a unique solution of an exponential martingale equation in the class ofBM Omartingales. The solution is used to characterize optimal martingale measures.

1

Introduction

Let (Ω,F, P) be a probability space with filtration F= (Ft, t∈ [0, T]). We assume that all local martingales with respect toFare continuous. HereT is a fixed time horizon andF=FT. Let M be a stable subspace of the space of square integrable martingales H2. Then its ordinary orthogonalM⊥is a stable subspace and any element of Mis strongly orthogonal to

any element of M⊥ (see, e.g. [3], [8]).

We consider the following exponential equation

ET(m)Eα

T(m⊥) =cexp{η}, (1)

whereηis a givenFT-measurable random variable andαis a given real number. A solution of equation (1) is a triple (c, m, m⊥), wherecis strictly positive constant,m∈ Mandm∈ M.

Here E(X) is the Doleans-Dade exponential ofX.

It is evident that if α= 1 then equation (1) admits an ”explicit” solution. E.g., ifα= 1 andη

is bounded, then using the unique decomposition of the martingale E(exp{η}/Ft)

E(exp{η}/Ft) =Eexp{η}+mt(η) +m⊥t(η), m(η)∈ M, m⊥(η)∈ M⊥, (2)

(2)

it is easy to verify that the triplec= 1

Eexp{η},

mt= Z t

0

1

E(exp{η}/Fs)dms(η), m

t =

Z t

0

1

E(exp{η}/Fs)dm

s(η)

satisfies equation (1). Note also that if α= 0 then a solution of (1) does not exist in general. In particular, in this case equation (1) admits a solution only ifηsatisfies (2) withm⊥(η) = 0.

Other cases are much more involved and (1) is equivalent to solve a certain martingale backward equation with square generator.

Equations of such type are arising in mathematical finance and they are used to characterize optimal martingale measures (see, Biagini, Guasoni and Pratelli (2000), Mania and Tevzadze (2000), (2003),(2005)). Note that equation (1) can be applied also to the financial market models with infinitely many assets (see M. De Donno, P. Guasoni, M. Pratelli (2003)). In Biagini at al (2000) an exponential equation of the form

ET(R.

0hsdWs)

ET(R.

0ksdMs)

=cexp{

Z T

0

λ2

sds} (3)

was considered (which corresponds to the caseα=−1). Assuming that any element ofH2 is representable as a sum of stochastic integralsH·W+K·M, whereW is a Brownian motion and

M is a martingale (not necessarily continuous) orthogonal toW, they identified the variance-optimal martingale measure as the solution of equation (3). In so-called extreme cases (already studied in Pham et al. (1998), Laurent and Pham (1999) using different methods), when the market price of risk λ is measurable with respect to the σ-algebras generated by W and M

respectively, they gave explicit solutions of (3)) providing an explicit form for the density of the variance-optimal martingale measure. These extreme cases correspond in our setting to the following conditions on the random variableη:

exp{η}=c(η) +mT(η), for a constant c(η) and mT(η)∈ M, (4)

exp{1

αη}=c(η)

+mT(η), for a constant c(η)and m(η)∈ M(5)

respectively. It is easy to see that if (4) is satisfied then the triple c = 1

c(η), m = (c(η) +

m(η))−1·m(η), m= 0 solves equation (1) and under condition (5) equation (1) is satisfied

ifm= 0,m⊥ = (c(η)+m(η))−1·m(η)andc=E−αexp{1

αη}.

Our aim is to prove the existence of a unique solution of equation (1) for arbitraryα6= 0 and

η of a general structure, assuming that it satisfies the following boundedness condition: B)η is anFT-measurable random variable of the form

η= ¯η+γAT, (6)

where ¯η∈L∞, γ is a constant andA= (At, t∈[0, T]) is a continuous F-adapted increasing process such that

E(AT −Aτ/Fτ)≤C

for all stopping timesτ for a constantC >0. The main statement of the paper is the following

Theorem 1. Let condition B) be satisfied. Then there is a constant γ0 > 0 such that for any |γ| ≤γ0 there exists a unique triple (c, m, m⊥), where c ∈R+, m∈ BM O∩ M, m⊥ ∈

(3)

In case α=−1 andγ= 0 this theorem was proved in [14].

In P. Grandits and T. Rheinl¨ander (2002), T. Rheinl¨ander (2005) and D. Hobson (2004) mini-mal entropy andq-optimal martingale measures are studied using a fundamental representation equation of type

q

2KT =MT −

q−1

2 hMiT +LT + 1 2+c

,

where KT =RT 0 λ

2

tdt, Mt =

Rt

0ϕu(dBu+qλudu),Lt = Rt

0ξudZu, B and Z are independent Brownian motions andλis fixed process. This equation is equivalent to (1) for suitableα,η

and for the probability measure dP˜ =ET(−qR·

0λsdMs)dP, since ˜Bt=Bt+q Rt

0λsdsand Zt are independent Brownian motions w.r.t. ˜P. Assumption B) guarantees the solvability of the equation either if ess supτE˜RT

τ q

2λ2

udu|Fτ

is small enough or ifKT is bounded.

One can show that equation (1) is equivalent to the following semimartingale backward equa-tion with the square generator

Yt=Y0−γ

2At− hLit− 1

αhL

it+Lt+L

t, YT =

1

2η.¯ (7)

We show that there exists a unique triple (Y, L, L⊥), where Y is a bounded continuous

semi-martingale,L∈BM O∩ M, L⊥BM O∩ M, that satisfies equation (7). If the filtrationF

is generated by a multidimensional Brownian motion and if AT is bounded, the existence of a solution of equation (7) follows from the results of M. Kobylanski (2000) and J.P. Lepeltier and J. San Martin (1998), where the BSDEs (Backward Stochasic Differential Equations) with generators satisfying the square growth conditions were considered. We prove existence and uniqueness of (7) (or (1)) by different methods.

In section 2, using the BM Onorm for martingales (LandL⊥) and theL([0, T]×Ω) norm

for semimartingales Y, we apply the fixed-point theorem to show an existence of a solution first in case whenL∞ norm of ¯η and constantγare sufficiently small. Then we construct the

solution for an arbitrary bounded ¯η.

In section 3 we construct a solution of equation (1) using the value process of a certain op-timization problem, for some values of the parameter α. We give also a necessary condition for equation (1) to admit a solution in the classBM O(or a bounded solutionY for equation (7)). This condition shows that we can’t expect an existence of a bounded solution of (7) for arbitraryγ.

2

Proof of the main Theorem

We recall the definition of BMO-martingales and of a similar notion for the processes of finite variation.

The square integrable continuous martingaleM belongs to the classBM Oif there is a constant

C >0 such that

E12(< M >T −< M >τ|Fτ)≤C, P−a.s.

for every stopping time τ. The smallest constant with this property (or +∞ if it does not exist) is called the BM Onorm ofM and is denoted by||M||BM O.

For the process of finite variationA we denote by vart

s(A) the variation on the segment [s, t].

If

(4)

for every stopping timeτ, let us denote by|A|ω the smallest constant with this property. We say that the processBstrongly dominates the processAand writeA≺B, if the difference

B−A ∈ A+loc, i.e., is a locally integrable increasing process. We shall use also the notation

ϕ·X for the stochastic integral with respect to the semimartingaleX.

Let N ∈ BM O(P) and dQ = ET(N)dP. Then Q is a probability measure equivalent to

P by Theorem 2.3 Kazamaki 1994). Denote by ψ = ψ(X) = hX, Ni −X the Girsanov’s transformation. It is well known that (see Kazamaki 1994 ) bothH2andBM Oare invariant under transformation ψ. Let M(Q) and M⊥(Q) be images of the mapping ψ for M and

M⊥respectively, . Note thatM(Q) andM⊥(Q) are stable orthogonal subspaces of the space

H2(Q) of square integrable martingales with respect toQ.

We shall need the following lemma to switch solutions of equation (1) for different final random variables.

Lemma 1. Let there existsm1, m⊥1 ∈BM O,m1∈ M, m⊥1 ∈ M⊥ such that

ET(m1)ETα(m⊥1) =c1exp{η1}. (8)

LetQbe a probability measure defined by

dQ=ET(m1+m⊥1)dP

and assume that there existsm2, m⊥2 ∈BM O(Q),m2∈ M(Q), m⊥2 ∈ M⊥(Q) such that

ET(m2)Eα

T(m⊥2) =c2exp{η2}. (9) Then there exists a solution of equation

ET(m)ETα(m⊥) =cexp{η1+η2}. (10)

Proof. Note that

dP dQ=E

−1

T (m1+m⊥1) =ET( ˜m1+ ˜m⊥1),

where ˜m1=hm1i −m1and ˜m⊥1 =hm⊥1i −m⊥1 areBM Omartingales underQ.

By Girsanov’s theoremm2andm⊥2 are special semimartingales underP with the decomposi-tion

m2= ˆm2+hm2,m˜1i, m2⊥= ˆm⊥2 +hm⊥2,m˜⊥1i

where ˆm2=m2− hm2, m˜1iand ˆm⊥2 =m⊥2 − hm⊥2,m˜⊥1iareBM O(P)-martingales according to Theorem 3.6 of Kazamaki (1994).

Girsanov’s theorem and the uniqueness of the canonical decomposition of special semimartin-gales imply that

hmˆ2, m1i=−hm2,m˜1i, hmˆ⊥2, m⊥1i=−hm⊥2,m˜⊥1i. (11)

Multiplying now equations (2.1) and (2.2) and using Yor’s formula we obtain

ET(m1+m2+hmˆ2, m1i)ETα(m

1 +m⊥2 +hmˆ⊥2, m⊥1i) =c1c2exp{η1+η2}. (12) By equality (11) and Theorem 3.6 of Kazamaki (1994)m2+hmˆ2, m1iand m⊥2 +hmˆ⊥2, m⊥1i areBM O(P) martingales. It is easy to see that these martingales are strongly orthogonal to each other. Therefore,c=c1c2, m=m1+m2+hmˆ2, m1iandm⊥=m⊥1 +m2⊥+hmˆ⊥2, m⊥1i satisfy equation (2.3).

(5)

Proposition 1. Let η be an FT-measurable random variable. If there exists a triple

Recall that ifM andN are continuous local martingales then (see, e.g., Jacod 1979)

Et(M)

Therefore, from (13) we have that

c′ET(ml− hml, li) =cEα

LetQbe a measure defined by

dQ=ET(l+α+ 1

i are BM O-martingales with respect to the measure Q according to

Theorem 3.6 of Kazamaki (1994) and corresponding Doleans-Dade exponentials are uniformly integrable Q-martingales. Therefore equality (14) holds for all t∈ [0, T], which implies that

c=c′ and

Proposition 2a. Letη be a boundedFT-measurable random variable. Then there exists a triple (c, m, m⊥), wherecR

+, m∈BM O∩ M, m⊥ ∈BM O∩ M⊥, that satisfies equation (1).

Proof. It is evident that equation (1) is equivalent to the following martingale equation

−lnc−1

2η one can write this equation in the form

c′− hLiT− 1 αhL

iT +LT +L

T =ξ. (16)

(6)

Let first show that there exists a solution (c, m, m⊥) of equation (16) if|ξ|

∞is small enough.

For brevity we shall use the notationhmitT =hmiT − hmitfor the square characteristic of a martingalem.

BMO-martingales andY is a semimartingale. UsingL∞([0, T]×Ω) norm for semimartingales

and BMO norms for martingales, we shall show that if the norm|ξ|∞is sufficiently small, then

there existsr >0 such that mapping (18) is a contraction in the ball

Br={(l, l⊥),||l+l⊥||BMO≤r}

Using the Ito formula forY2

T −Yt2 and (18),(19) we have integrable martingales. Therefore, the stochastic integral Y ·(L+L⊥) is a martingale and

taking conditional expectations in (20) we have

(7)

Now we shall show that the mapping (18) is a contraction on the ball Br from the space

On the other hand using the Kunita-Watanabe inequality, elementary inequalities (a+b)2 2(a2+b2) andhl+l, l+ 1

are satisfied simultaneously. Thus we obtain that if |ξ|∞ is small enough, then the mapping

(18) is a contraction and by fixed point theorem equation (17) (and hence equation (1)) admits a unique solution. In particular if|ξ|∞≤ 41β then the BMO-norm of the solution is less than

1

β.

To get rid of the assumption that|ξ|∞ should be small enough, let us use the Lemma 1. Let

us take an integern≥1 so that equation

c1ET(m)ETα(m⊥) = exp{

1

nξ} (25)

admits a solution. Let dQ=ET(m1+m⊥1)dP, where (m1, m⊥1)∈BM O(P) is a solution of (25). Since the norm|ξ|∞ is invariant with respect to an equivalent change of measure and

since the Girsanov transformation is an isomorphism ofBM O(P) ontoBM O(Q), similarly as above one can show that there exists a pairm2, m⊥2 ∈BM O(Q) that satisfies equation (25). Therefore by Lemma 1, there exists a solution of equation

c2ET(m)ETα(m

) = exp{2

(8)

Using now Lemma 1 to equation (26) by induction we obtain that there exists a solution of equation (1).

Remark. For the solution (Y, m, m⊥) of (17) the following estimate is true

|Yt| ≤ |ξ|∞ for all t∈[0, T].

Indeed, since m, m⊥ BM O, the process Y is a uniformly integrable martingale under Q,

wheredQ=ET(L+αL⊥)dP then (17). Therefore

Yt=EQ(ξ/Ft)≤ |ξ|

∞.

Let us consider now the case, where the final random variable is of the form η =γAT for a constantγ and an increasing process (At, t∈[0, T]).

Proposition 2b. Assume that η = γAT, |A|ω < ∞ and |γ| < 2|A|∧|ω1. Then there exists a unique triple (c, m, m⊥), where c R

+, m∈ BM O∩ M, m⊥ ∈ BM O∩ M⊥, that satisfies equation (1).

Proof. The proof is similar to the proof of Proposition 2a. The only difference is that in equation (19)ξis replaced by ¯γ(AT−At), where ¯γ= 1

2γ and equation (17) is replaced by the BSDE

Yt=Y0−γAt¯ − hL+L⊥, L+ 1

αL

it+Lt+L

t, YT = 0. (27)

Therefore, applying the Itˆo formula forY2

t and after using the same arguments we obtain

Yt2+E(hL+L⊥itT/Ft)≤

≤2|Y|∞¯γE(AT −At/Ft) +βE(hl+l⊥itT/Ft)≤ (28)

≤ |Y|2∞+ 2¯γ2E2(AT −At/Ft) + 2β2E2(hl+l⊥itT/Ft)

and hence

|L+L⊥|2BMO≤2¯γ 2|A|2

ω+ 2β

2|l+l|4 BMO.

If|γ||A|ω¯ < 41β (or equivalently|γ|<2|A|∧|ω1) we can takersatisfying the inequalities

r2≥2¯γ2|A|2ω+ 2β2r4and 2βr <1. (29)

Therefore|l+l⊥|

BMO≤rimplies|L+L⊥|2BMO≤2¯γ2|A|ω+ 2β2r4≤r2.

The contraction property of the mapping is proved similarly to Proposition 2a and the Lipschitz constant is again 2βr.

The proof of Theorem 1. The uniqueness is proved in Proposition 1. An existence is a consequence of Proposition 2a, Proposition 2b and Lemma 1.

3

Solution as a value process of an optimization problem

In this section we shall construct the solution of equation (1) using the value process of a certain optimization problem for some values of parameterα.

(9)

D) there existsm∗∈ MBM Osuch that

E(eAT−Aτ

EtT1−α(m∗)/Fτ)≤C (30)

for all stopping timesτ, for someC >0, whereEtT(m∗) = ET(m∗)

Et(m∗).

Remark. It is evident that condition D) is satisfied if

E(eAT−Aτ

/Fτ)≤C (31)

for all stopping timesτ, for someC >0 and vice versa if condition D) andα∈¯(0,1) are satisfied then there exists the measure dQ=ET(m∗∗)dP, m∗∗∈ M⊥∩BM Osuch that

EQ(eAT−Aτ/Fτ)C.

Let us introduce the value process

Vt=Vt(α) = ess inf

m⊥∈M⊥ E(e

AT−At

EtT1−α(m⊥)|Ft). (32)

Note thatVtis value process of an optimization problem, which contains the problem of finding of theq-optimal martingale measure dual to the power utility maximization problem.

Theorem 2. Letα <0 and letη be anFT-measurable random variable of the formη =AT,

where L+L⊥ is the martingale part ofV, satisfies equation (1).

Moreover lnVtis a unique bounded solution of (17).

If E(AT −Aτ/Fτ) ≤ C for every stopping time τ and if there exists a triple (c, m, m⊥),

c ∈ R+, m ∈ BM O∩ M, m⊥ ∈BM O∩ M⊥, satisfying equation (1), then condition D) is fulfilled.

Proof. It is evident that

1≤Vt≤C, (33)

where the first inequality follows from Jensen’s inequality and the second follows from con-dition D). Similarly to Theorem 1 of [15] one can show that Vt defined by (32) is a special semimartingale which is a unique bounded solution of the BSDE

Vt=−

it is not difficult to see that the triple (1/V0, m, m⊥) satisfies equation (1). Indeed, applying the Itˆo formula forlnVtfrom equation (34) we have

(10)

Using the boundary condition and (34) we obtain the equality (1).

Assume now that there exists a triplec∈R+, m∈BM O∩M, m⊥∈BM O∩M⊥that satisfies equation (1). Consider the process

Yt=ce−At

Et(m)Etα(m⊥).

Equality (1) implies thatYT = 1, hence

Yt=eAT−AtE−1

tT(m)E

−α tT (m

) (36)

and

lnYt=E(AT −At/Ft) +1

2E(< m >tT /Ft) +

α

2E(< m

>tT /Ft).

Sincem andm⊥ belong to BM OandE(AT At/Ft)const, the processlnYtis bounded.

SinceY is strictly positive, this implies that the processY satisfies the two-sided inequality

0< c≤Yt≤C. (37)

(in particular,Yt=Vtby the uniqueness of (34)) Therefore (36) and (37) imply that

E(eAT−AtE1−α

tT (m

)/Ft) =YtE(EtT(m)EtT(m)/Ft) =YtC.

Remark. If 0< α <1 and there is a triple (c, m, m⊥), wherecR

+, m∈BM O∩ M, m⊥∈

BM O∩ M⊥ satisfying equation (1), then there exists C >0 such that

E(eAT−Aτ

/Fτ)≤C

for all stopping timesτ.

Indeed, similarly as above, the process Y defined by (36) satisfies inequality (37) and from (36) we have

E(eAT−At

/Ft) =YtE(EtT(m)EtTα(m⊥)/Ft).

Since 0< α <1 and since Et(m⊥) is a martingale under the measuredQ=ET(m)dP, using the H¨older inequality we obtain from the latter equality that

E(eAT−At

/Ft) =YtEQ(EtTα(m⊥)/Ft)≤

≤C(EQ(EtT(m)/Ft)α=C.

This remark and Theorem 2 show that ifγis large enough so that conditionE(eγ(AT−Aτ)/Fτ)

constis not satisfied then the bounded solution of the equation (27) does not exist.

References

[1] F. Biagini, P. Guasoni and M. Pratelli, Mean variance hedging for stochastic volatil-ity models,Math. Finance,Vol. 10. no. 2, 2000,109-123.MR1802593

(11)

[3] C. Dellacherie and P. A. Meyer, Probabilit´es et potentiel. Chapitres V a VIII. Th´eorie des martingales.Actualit´es Scientifiques et Industrielles Hermann, Paris, (1980).

MR566768

[4] M. De Donno, P. Guasoni, M. Pratelli,Superreplication and Utility Maximization in Large Financial Markets, Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 115 (2005), no. 12, 2006-2022, MR2178505MR2178505

[5] N. El Karoui, S. Peng and M.C. Quenez, Backward stochastic differential equations in finance,Math. Finance, Vol.7, no. 1, (1997), 1-71.MR1434407

[6] P. Grandits and T. Rheinl¨ander, On the minimal entropy martingale measure,The Annals of Probab.30 (2002), no. 3, 1003-1038.MR1920099

[7] D. Hobson, Stochastic volatility models, correlation, andq-optimal martingale measure, Math. Finance, Vol.14, no. 4, (2004), 537-556.MR2092922

[8] J. Jacod, Calcule Stochastique et probl`emes des martingales. Lecture Notes in Math., Springer, Berlin, N. 714, (1979).MR542115

[9] N. Kazamaki, Continuous exponential martingales and BMO, Lecture Notes in Math., Springer, Berlin, N. 1579, (1994).MR1299529

[10] M. Kobylanski, Backward stochastic differential equation and partial differential equa-tions with quadratic growth, The Annals of Probability, vol. 28, N2,(2000), 558-602.

MR1782267

[11] J.P. Laurent and H. Pham, Dynamic programming and mean-variance hedging, Fi-nance Stoch. no. 3, (1999), 83-110.MR1805322

[12] J.P. Lepeltier and J. San Martin, Existence for BSDE with superlinear-quadratic coefficient, Stoch. Stoch. Rep. 63 (1998), 227-240.MR1658083

[13] M. Mania and R. Tevzadze, A Semimartingale Bellman equation and the variance-optimal martingale measure, Georgian Math. J. 7 no. 4 (2000), 765-792.MR1811929

[14] M. Mania and R. Tevzadze,A martingale equation of exponential type, From Stochas-tic Calculus to MathemaStochas-tical Finance, The Shiryaev Festschrift, Springer, (2005), 507-516.

MR2230641

[15] M. Mania, M. Santacroce and R. Tevzadze, A Semimartingale backward equation related to thep-optimal martingale measure and the minimal price of contingent claims, Stoch. Processes and Related Topics, Stochastics Monogr., 12 Taylor&Francis. (2002), 169-202.

[16] M. Mania and R. Tevzadze, A Semimartingale Bellman equation and the variance-optimal martingale measure under general information flow, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, Vol. 42, no. 5, (2003), 1703-1726.MR2046382

[17] T. Rheinl¨ander, An entropy approach to the Stein and Stein model with correlation, Finance Stochastics, no. 9, (2005),399-413.MR2211715

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

Televisi seharusnya dapat menyediakan hal serupa, dimana tidak terlalu “vulgar” dalam pemberitaan tentang salah satu kandidat dalam perputaran tahun politik yang terjadi,

Demikian pengumuman / pemberitahuan ini disampaikan untuk diketahui, dengan ketentuan apabila terdapat kekeliruan akan diperbaiki

Bio Farma (Persero) Bandung adalah satu-satunya industri biologi yang memproduksi vaksin dan sera di Indonesia, juga salah satu dari bebrapa produsen dunia

Jadi dalam kesimpulan tulisan diatas perlu digarisbawahi bahwa pendidikan literasi media harus dilakukan tidak hanya untuk anak- anak dan remaja namun seluruh lapisan yang

Sumber Dana : APBN Satuan Kerja Dinas Peternakan Provinsi Kalimantan Selatan Tahun Anggaran 2012. Berdasarkan Berita Acara Hasil Pelelangan Nomor :

Pesan verbal yang terjadi ini terdiri dari pesan verbal yang bersifat informatif dan pesan verbal yang bersifat persuasif; (2) Proses komunikasi terapeutik bidan dan paraji sebagai

Untuk dapat mencapai tujuan tersebut, maka dilakukan langkah-langkah yang terdiri dari tahap analisis sistem dengan Unified Modelling Language (UML), sedangkan untuk

Pengguna Anggaran Kegiatan Penyusunan Rencana Investasi Pembangunan Jangka