• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:I:International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour & Research:Vol4.Issue3.1998:

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "Directory UMM :Data Elmu:jurnal:I:International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour & Research:Vol4.Issue3.1998:"

Copied!
10
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

Financing

preferences

239

The financing preferences of

small firm owners

Robert T. Hamilton

University of Canterbury, Christchurch, New Zealand, and

Mark A . Fox

Lincoln University, Canterbury, New Zealand

Introduction

Most small firms will never be able to raise all the funding they would like from banks and other institutions. In this crude sense there w ill alw ay s be a deficiency in the funding of the sector equal to the difference between the total demand for funding and that part of this demand which qualifies for funding suppo rt. T his paper focuses mo re narrow ly on the debt versus equity preferences revealed in the initial and ongoing financing of small firms drawn from a cross-section of the New Zealand economy[1]. W hile pointing to a gap in the supply of funds, particularly institutional equity capital, previous local research (Coopers and Lybrand, 1993) attributed most failings in the capital market to small firm owners rather than the suppliers of funds. Owners were portrayed as unable to understand the appropriate form of capital (debt versus equity) and to have unrealistic expectations of deals involving the introduction of new equity. It is the consequent restriction of choice that leads small firms to become burdened with excessive levels of debt. We begin the paper by outlining our research objective and the methodology used to pursue this. T he sample of small firms used in the study is then profiled. T his sets the scene for a discussion of the initial and ongoing financing preferences revealed by small firm owners. T he paper concludes that supposed gaps in the supply of finance to small firms might be in part the consequence rather than the cause of financing decisions of the business owners.

Research objectives

T here is some debate in the literature over the extent to which leverage levels vary with the size of firm and the reasons for this. International comparative studies by Remmers et al.(1974) and Peterson and Schulman (1987) reach different conclusions. T he first of these studies found the debt/total assets ratio to be independent of firm size. In contrast Peterson and Schulman reported debt/total assets ratio to first rise and then fall with size of firm. W hile much depends on the precise definition of what is to be treated as debt, it is accepted that small owner-managed companies operate with higher levels of debt than do larger firms (Holmes and Kent, 1991) and have a particularly high reliance on short-term debt.

(2)

IJEBR

4,3

240

One possible ex planation fo r this reso rt to debt is that it is ex ternally imposed, reflecting a persistent gap in the capital market, which denies small firms access to more appropriate forms of finance (e.g. equity and long-term debt). Such a gap was first identified in 1931 (MacMillan Committee, 1931) and has been rediscovered in many subsequent inquiries (e.g. Bolton Committee Report, 1971; Stanworth and Gray, 1991, pp. 112-50; Tamari, 1980; University of Cambridge, 1992). A n alternative explanation comes from the extension of the work of Myers (1984) to the small firm sector (Holmes and Kent, 1991; Scherr et al., 1990). T his suggests that small firm owners operate without targeting an optimal debt:equity ratio and reveal a strong preference for those financing options that minimise intrusion into their business. Following Myers (1984, p. 589), observed debt ratios will reflect the cumulative need for external finance over an extended period and these will vary both between industries and among firms in the same industry. The inter-industry differences will reflect differences in asset type and intensity. Intra-industry variation reflects firm-level differences in initial capitalisation and the ongoing capacity to retain earnings. Small firm owners will try to meet their finance needs from a pecking order of, first, their “own” money (p ersonal sav ing s; retained earning s); second, sho rt-term bo rrowing s; third, long er term debt; and, least preferred of all, from the introduction of new equity investors, which represents the maximum intrusion (Cosh and Hughes, 1994). If small firm owners in different countries reveal such a preference ordering, then perhaps the nature of the long-standing finance gap needs to be reconsidered.

Methodology

The method adopted here was to investigate directly the financing preferences of small firm owners using a postal questionnaire administered in September 1995. We also sought to incorporate age and size effects, two related variables that have been associated with financial structure. To deal with the first of these dimensions we surveyed 185 “new” businesses, all less than four years old (i.e. founded in 1992 or later) and 370 “established” businesses more than five years of age (i.e. founded in 1989 or earlier). Businesses were also selected on the basis of size: all employed fewer than 100 people in 1995. Samples of different ages provided us with a basis of identifying any changes over time in the funding preferences of small business owners.

(3)

Financing

preferences

241

intensity could only be applied to manufacturing industries and we sought a wider cross-section. To this end we also brought into the survey small non-manufacturing firms operating in areas which appeared to be experiencing some g rowth. T hese areas were computer software development; inbound tourism-related; and advertising agencies. A further reason for adding these businesses is that they will generally have principal assets, which are both intang ible and po rtable in contrast to the tang ible and fix ed nature of manufacturing assets.

The survey reached a total of 555 firms spread among the range of industry sectors described above. The composition of the survey and the response rates are in the A ppendix. T he names, addresses and number of employees were obtained from the 1995 edition of T he New Zealand Business W ho’s W ho. T he overall response rate of 34 per cent was in line with expectations based on comparable surveys which have been reported in the literature and sufficient for the statistical analyses undertaken.

A ge and size profiles

T he evidence on age and size (number of full-time employees) is set out in Table I. Note the age range of the sample (the oldest firm having been founded in 1905) and the relationship between age and size (full-time employees).

For ease of reference we henceforth refer to these three g roups of firms as “new” (founded 1992-1994); “established” (founded 1980-1989); and “mature” (founded before 1980). Not only were the new businesses significantly smaller than their older counterparts, they also had less ambition in terms of future size. The intended maximum size of the new and established firms was 13 employees while that for the mature group was 22, a size already attained by many of the oldest firms. However, that more recently founded firms currently intend to be smaller than older firms may reflect the possibility that future size is positively related to current size. It is also the case that our measure of size (number of full-time employees) may understate g rowth intentions where these involve increased efficiency or greater use of outsourcing. However, these caveats are unlikely to apply to more than a few of the firms. The profiles in Table I also have a bearing on the targeting of publicly funded job creation schemes. T he stark policy choice has been between funding start-ups with high rates of failure and supporting further g rowth in established firms where the failure rates are reduced. Here the new firms have created on average eight jobs in their first two

Period Number of Average age Current full- Intended founded firmsa (in years) time employees maximum size

Prior to 1980 45 31 17 22 1980-1989 52 10 13 13 1992-1994 77 2 8 13

Note: a12 firms did not provide full data

Table I.

(4)

IJEBR

4,3

242

years and, bearing in mind their intended max imum siz e, most of the employment potential of small firms may already have been realised within these first two years[3]. However, mature firms, though larger but less numerous and more slowly growing, also offer the prospect of further job creation. T his supports the view that resource allocation should be determined by the growth potential rather than age of business (Smallbone and North, 1995).

Initial financing

Initial funding preferences have been the subject of international research and are a useful focus in part because firm age has not yet become a variable capable of influencing this decision. Peterson and Schulman (1987) provide a general model relating the financial structure of the small firm to its age (or size). Here the ownership ratio (i.e. shareholders’ funds as a proportion of total assets) is at its highest in new firms; then falls for a time with age/size, before rising again in larger mature businesses. This general pattern established by these authors in 12 countries has been explained in terms of information asymmetry and agency problems. T he problem of information asymmetry is endemic to small business lending and it compounds concerns about the principal (bank)-agent (small business) relationship (see Storey, 1994, pp. 204-52). The issue here is the ability of the lender to control the borrower. Indeed the borrower may adopt high risk, high reward strategies secure in the knowledge that their risk is fixed and that all capital gains will accrue to them as owners. T he lender remains with the downside risk of writing-off the loan that is not compensated by the prospect of gain if the business performs well. Monitoring is possible to some extent but its costs are largely independent of loan size, i.e. the agency costs are highest for the smaller loans that we would expect in the new business area. Consequently, we would expect the bulk of the initial financing to have come from the founder. The findings are contained in Table II that reports the percentages of firms reliant on the different sources as their main source of initial funding.

W hile the savings of the founders continue to be the dominant source of initial capital[4], the proportion of businesses dependent on such funding fell from 76 per cent of the oldest firms to 60 per cent of the newest group; a difference in proportions which is significant at the 10 per cent level. T he recent increased involvement of financial institutions (mainly banks) in funding new businesses may indicate an improved ability on their part to monitor and control new

Period founded

Main source of initial funding Before 1980 1980-1989 1992-1994 Founder’s own savings 76 73 60 Founder’s immediate family 4 8 8 Financial institutions 11 13 24 Other main sourcesa 9 6 8 Note: aT hese included friends of the founder, large companies and small local firms Table II.

(5)

Financing

preferences

243

enterprise lending. It may also point to a realisation by the banks that for new firms, information asymmetry may now operate in their favour. T his would be so if bank staff were better able than the founder to assess the prospects of the proposed business (Storey, 1994, p. 206). But a more likely explanation is that there are just more new firms around who are willing and able to provide the collateral on the basis of which limited loan funds can be allocated (Cowling and Westhead, 1996). Interviews conducted with senior bankers confirmed that this greater availability of collateral was indeed a key factor in the change[5].

Two other supply-side developments appear to have contributed to this apparent increase in institutional involvement with new business. First, the banks were discovering that their original customers’ financing needs were changing. Many of those who had become customers to obtain housing loans were now seeking new loans for business purposes, a development seen as positive by the banks. Second, most banks did not distinguish between housing and business loans. T he loans would be secured against the borrower’s house but their purpose was to support the financial requirements of a new business. Capital adequacy rules adopted by the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, as a signatory to the Basle A ccord, classify housing mortgages more favourably than business loans for the purpose of determining a bank’s capital adequacy ratios. T his translates into a lower cost of borrowing for businesses that could be funded in this manner. The banks, by meeting their customers’ requirements in this way, established not only a profitable small business lending base but also the diversified income stream favoured by the international rating agencies.

Ongoing financing

If we follow the theory of Peterson and Schulman (1987), we would expect that as time passes firms become more acceptable to lenders, i.e. debt levels will rise causing ownership ratios to fall. Our information on financial structure is confined to measures of the ownership ratio that we asked our respondents to compute from their most recent balance sheet. We confined the measure of financial structure in this way because, measured as shareholders funds/total assets, it is among the easier ratios to compute and did not require us or the respondent to judge what is debt and how to distinguish among short, medium and long -term debt. T he ow nership ratio is also v ital from the lender’s perspective, a matter we return to later in this paper.

T he survey evidence relating to the ongoing financing preferences of these small firm owners is set out in Table III.

Period Ownership ratio Percentage of profit retained Percentage of firms able founded (per cent) (intended) to retain intended share Prior to 1980 44.0 44.6 73

1980-1989 45.6 40.9 79 1992-1994 44.3 53.1 60

Table III.

(6)

IJEBR

4,3

244

In fact the average ownership ratios between our samples of different ages are not significantly different, contrary to expectations based on the findings of Peterson and Schulman (1987). T his then opens up the question of how small firm owners do provide for the ongoing financing needs of their businesses.

Our first approach to this w as to discover the immediate financing preferences of these owners and here we found no significant differences among new, established and mature firms. If they had to raise more ongoing funding in the next three months, the preferences expressed were indeed unaffected by time in business. Of the new group, 41 per cent would seek only debt, as would 41 per cent of the established g roup. T he mature firms appeared the most wedded to debt with 54 per cent confining any new funding to this form of finance. However, as we indicated, the difference in these proportions (54 per cent versus 41 per cent) is not significant. T he issue of ownership and control was, as expected, central to the attitude towards introducing new equity. On average 41 per cent of the owners would consider a new equity investor if this did not affect their control of the business but, if new equity meant some weakening or sharing of control, then only 22 per cent of owners would be interested. Further scrutiny of these responses also suggested that many who would be prepared to share or lose control were those who were keen to find a way to realise their investment in the business, i.e. they saw new equity as their way out of the business.

T he picture that emerges here is consistent with the pecking order theory proposed by Myers (1984). T he financing preferences at the outset are constrained towards owners’ equity (personal savings) but then establish a preference for external debt over equity which is independent of the age of the small firm. Within this set of preferences, we would expect retained earnings to feature as a prominent source of internal funding, particularly so for new businesses that have fewer financing options available to them. However, while new firms may desire to retain a higher share of earnings, the economics of business start-up are such as to militate against high retention ratios. In other words, we might expect to observe more difficulty in attaining the higher desired rates of retention in new firms. T hese expectations are borne out by the data presented in Table III above. T he new firms were aiming to retain most profit (averaging 53.1 per cent), higher than either of the other g roups and significantly higher (5 per cent level) than the 40.9 per cent of the established group of firms. T hese intended retention rates have also to be considered in the light of the rather modest growth intentions of these firms that we commented on above. T his points to a preference to internalise the financing of these firms. However, at the time of the survey, only 60 per cent of the new firms were able to achieve their intended rate of retention, less than either of the older groupings and significantly below (5 per cent level) the 79 per cent reported for established firms.

(7)

Financing

preferences

245

retention rate. W hen additional funding must come from beyond the firm, we have seen that debt is much preferred over new equity partners. A s noted previously, some have interpreted this preference for debt to be due to the know ledge g ap on the part of small firm ow ners, i.e. that ow ners fail to comprehend the differing cash flow implications of debt versus equity. We do not support this contention. Debt is the strongly preferred form of external funding despite carrying with it the more onerous and complex cashflow implications, e.g. regular scheduling of interest payments as a prior charge and scheduling the loan repayment over the term of the loan. T he real issue here is how these small single-manager businesses go about framing their funding decisions. T hey tend not to operate with much forward planning and so most funding decisions end up presenting themselves as cash problems. W hen the need is to raise cash quickly the dominant preference ordering puts the most easily accessed debt at the head of all external sources (but behind internal sources). A predilection towards debt is therefore manifest but this can be explained without resort to gaps in either knowledge or in supply of particular types of funds. T hese small firm owners simply prefer to have all of debt-laden business rather than merely a share in the control of a relatively debt-free operation.

T his draws attention to the attitude of small business owners to their ownership ratios, i.e. the extent to which their shareholder funds account for the total assets of the business. T his ratio, or correlates of it, feature prominently in financial theory and in any discussion of small business lending seen from the lender’s perspective. Lenders are influenced by knowing how much the owners have actually been able to fund the assets of the business. If this share is less than say 50 per cent, then a lender will begin to question the commitment of the owners to the business and hence be reluctant to lend without some increase in equity. But if financing preferences were such as to rank internal ahead of external sources, and new equity as the least preferred of all external sources, then we would expect small firm owners to be much less concerned than lenders with their ownership ratios. We obtained ownership ratios from 120 businesses who also gave their opinion on the number they had just computed. T hese data are in Table IV.

Number in each ownership range

Opinions of owners Up to 25% 26-50% 51-75% 76-100% Total Too high 0 1 4 3 8 A bout right 6 19 12 4 41 Too low 14 13 2 0 29 Not concerned 11 8 10 13 42 Total 31 41 28 20 120

Table IV.

(8)

IJEBR

4,3

246

T he first point to note is that 35 per cent of the owners said they were simply “not concerned” with the ownership ratio even though this was no greater than 50 per cent in 19 of the 42 businesses. In other words, this key ratio is unlikely to influence their financial preferences. To put this another way, of the 72 owners with ratios less than 50 per cent, only 27 (or 38 per cent) expressed the opinion that their ratio was “too low”. However, while 45 per cent of owners (14 out of 31) do concede that their ownership ratios of 25 per cent or less are indeed “too low”, if owners in this group had to raise new ongoing funding in the next three months, only five of the 31 (16 per cent) would seek equity only: 13 (42 per cent) would attempt to raise more debt. Here again it seems that the financial preferences of many owners are more pervasive than the consequences of these for the ongoing funding and indeed stability of their businesses.

Conclusions

We are not suggesting here that all new and small firms either could or should be funded. Bank lending, for example, must be subject to rationing. W hat we do propose is that debt levels in small firms do reflect a demand-side preference ordering and are not just the manifestation of supply-side deficiencies. In drawing this discussion to its end, there is an apt statement of small firm financing decisions in Norton (1991, p. 174) as follows:

In small business and entrepreneurial firms, managerial beliefs and desires will play an especially important role in determining capital structure ... [and] models must include the role of management preferences, beliefs, and expectations if we are to better understand capital structure policy.

Our evidence g ained directly from small business owners from a range of industry sectors in New Zealand lends support to this view. T hese owners do appear to have a set of preferences over funding sources which, for the most part, are independent of age (or size) and have little to do with the consequent financial structures of their balance sheets. Internal funding sources commencing with the cash savings of the founders and then extending to retained earnings are the most preferred since these do least to inhibit the independence of the owner. T his view of how the financing preferences of owners are established enables one to explain small firm financial structures without resort to any shortcomings or gaps in the supply of finance. Indeed one may even argue that any apparent gap is in part a consequence rather than a cause of the financing preferences of small firm owners.

Notes

1. T he research was commissioned by the New Zealand Ministry of Commerce and we are particularly grateful to Richard Dore and Matt Roy for their support. T he views expressed here are those of the authors alone.

(9)

Financing

preferences

247

3. It also seems that most new businesses will survive two years. Of the 22,946 businesses created in New Zealand in 1988, 69 per cent were still operating in 1990. Source: Business A ctivity 1992-93.

4. It is interesting to note that our combined data for New Zealand are almost identical to the percentages reported for a sample of Australian firms in Scott and Kent (1991).

5. T his recent greater involvement of financial institutions may also be one reason why 54 per cent of the newer group were operating with a written business plan compared with only 29 per cent of the older firms (a difference significant at the 5 per cent level).

References

Bolton Committee Report(1971), Report of the Committee of Inquiry on Small Firms, HMSO, London.

Business A ctivity 1992-93, (1994), Statistics New Zealand, Wellington.

Coopers and Lybrand (1993), Factors A ffecting the Supply of Capital for Small Company Growth, New Zealand Ministry of Commerce, Wellington.

Cosh, A .D. and Hughes, A . (1994), “Size, financial structure and profitability”, in Hughes, A . and Storey, D.J. (Eds), Finance and the Small Firm, Routledge, London.

Cowling, M. and Westhead, P. (1996), “Bank lending decisions and small firms: does size matter?”, International Journal of Entrepreneurial and Behavioural Research, Vol. 2 No. 2, pp. 52-68.

Frater, P., Stuart, G., Rose, D. and A ndrews, G. (1995), T he New Zealand Innovation Environment,

T he Berl Foundation, Wellington.

Holmes, S. and Kent, P. (1991), “A n empirical analysis of the financial structure of small and large Australian manufacturing enterprises”,Journal of Small Business Finance,Vol. 1 No. 2, pp. 141-54.

MacMillan Committee (1931), Report of the Committee on Finance and Industry, HMSO, London. Myers, S. (1984), “T he capital structure puzzle”, Journal of Finance,July, pp. 595-62.

New Zealand Business W ho’s W ho(1995), Financial Press, Wellington.

Norton, E. (1991), “Capital structure and small growth firms”, Journal of Small Business Finance,

Vol. 1 No. 2, pp. 161-77.

Peterson, R. and Shulman, J. (1987), “ Capital structure of g row ing small firms: a twelve country study on becoming bankable”,International Small Business Journal, Vol. 5 No. 4, pp. 10-22.

Remmers, L., Stonehill, A ., Wright, R. and Beekhuisen, T. (1974), “Industry and size as debt ratio determinants in manufacturing internationally”, Financial M anagement, Vol. 36 No. 3, pp. 879-88.

Scherr, F., Sugrue, T. and Ward, J. (April 1990), “Financing the small firm startup: determinants of debt use”, Proceedings Second A nnual Small Firm Finance Research Symposium.

Smallbone, D. and North, D. (1995), “Targeting established SMEs: does their age matter?”,

International Small Business Journal,Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 47-64.

Stanworth, J. and Gray, C. (1991), Bolton 20 Years On: T he Small Firm in the 1990s,Paul Chapman, London.

Storey, D.J. (1994), Understanding the Small Business Sector, Routledge, London.

Tamari, M. (1980), “T he financial structure of the small firm – an international comparison of corporate accounts in the USA , France, UK, Israel and Japan”, A merican Journal of Small Business, April-June, pp. 20-34.

(10)

IJEBR

4,3

248

A ppendix

Export A ge of Number Usable Response Industry type intensity firms sent replies rate (% ) Manufacturing High New 54 21 39 Manufacturing Low New 56 23 41 Manufacturing High Established 108 27 25 Manufacturing Low Established 112 30 27 Non-manufacturing – New 75 33 44 Non-manufacturing – Established 150 52 35

Totals 555 186 34

Table A I.

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

[r]

Kepala Biro Perencanaan dan Organisasi Badan Urusan Adm inist rasi

Lampiran D.2 Tabel Hasil uji coba Pretest dan Postest soal penguasaan konsep kelas kontrol

Perusahaan BLESS COM ingin mengimplementasikan sistem informasi e-commerce dalam hal promosi penjualan produk mereka untuk meningkatkan jumlah profit perusahaan, dikarenakan

Penelitian ini bertujuan untuk mengkaji sungai Cigasong, Majalengka sebagai media model pembelajaran Creative Problem Solving (CPS) terhadap peningkatan penguasaan

a) MySQL merupakan sistem manajemen database. Database merupakan struktur penyimpanan data. Untuk menambah, mengakses, dan memproses data yang disimpan dalam sebuah database

rumusan masalah penelitian adalah “ Bagaimanakah kelayakan sungai Cigasong dijadikan sebagai media pembelajaran Creative Problem Solving. (CPS) materi pencemaran air pada

[r]