• Tidak ada hasil yang ditemukan

Country level corruption and accounting choice: research & development capitalisation under IFRS

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

Membagikan "Country level corruption and accounting choice: research & development capitalisation under IFRS"

Copied!
51
0
0

Teks penuh

(1)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2979300 1

Country level corruption and accounting choice: research & development capitalisation under IFRS

Francesco Mazzi

Richard Slack

Ioannis Tsalavoutas*

Fanis Tsoligkas

June 2017

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments received from Paul André, Andreas Kreß, Stergios Leventis, Darren Duxbury, Christian Stadler, Ian Tonks and the participants of the EUFIN Workshop (Fribourg, September 2016), BAFA Scottish Area Group Conference (Glasgow, August 2016) and Financial Reporting and Business Communication Conference FRBC (Bristol, July 2016) and seminar participants at the University of Bath (November, 2016), HEC Lausanne (February, 2017), Newcastle Business School (March, 2017), and 40th Annual EAA Conference (Valencia, May 2017).

*Corresponding author.

Francesco Mazzi is at the University of Florence (Economics and Management School, Accounting and Finance Division, Via delle Pangette 9, Building D6, 50127, Florence, Italy, E-mail: francesco.mazzi@unifi.it).

Richard Slack is at Durham University (Durham University Business School, Durham University Business School, Queen's Campus, H115, Wolfson Building, University Boulevard, Thornaby, Stockton on Tees, TS17 6BH, England, UK. E-mail: richard.slack@durham.ac.uk).

Ioannis Tsalavoutas is at the University of Glasgow (Adam Smith Business School, West Quadrangle, Main Building, Room G683, University Avenue, Glasgow, G12 8QQ, Scotland, UK. E-mail: ioannis.tsalavoutas@glasgow.ac.uk).

(2)

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2979300 2

Country level corruption and accounting choice: research & development capitalisation under IFRS

Abstract

We examine the influence of country-level corruption on the capitalisation of development

costs. IAS 38 mandates that development costs must be capitalised if specified conditions are

met. However, this requires judgement and hence may be subject to managerial opportunism

resulting in over-capitalisation. We find that there is a positive relation between

country-level corruption and the amount of development costs capitalised. Moreover, the higher the

levels of corruption, the lower the contribution of capitalised development costs to future

profitability. Further, we find that the amount capitalised and its contribution to future

profitability is influenced by domestic corruption only for less international firms.

Keywords: R&D; IFRS; corruption; accounting choice; future performance; internationalisation.

(3)

3 1. Introduction

There is ongoing debate as to whether International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS)

adoption necessarily improves accounting quality through a uniform framework for

accounting and reporting across countries, or if due to specific country characteristics,

disparity remains an issue (Ball, 2006; Ball, Robin, & Wu, 2003; Lehman, 2005; Nobes,

2006; Weetman, 2006). In this context, Houqe, Monem, Tareq, and van Zijl (2016) positively

argue that mandatory adoption of IFRS improves earnings quality in adopting countries as

inter alia IFRS are designed to reduce managerial discretion to manage or smooth earnings

(and see Ball, 2006; Shah, Liang, & Akbar, 2013). In contrast, ‘the inherent flexibility in

principles-based standards could provide greater opportunity for firms to manage earnings’

(Barth, Landsman, & Lang, 2008, p. 468).

One specific area of contention within IFRS in this regard is the treatment of research and

development (hereafter R&D) costs. IAS 38 Intangible Assets clearly sets out a number of

conditions under which development costs are to be capitalised. Arguably, by imposing

restrictive conditions, the discretion involved in R&D capitalisation is reduced (Markarian,

Pozza, & Prencipe, 2008; Matolcsy & Wyatt, 2006). Thus, one would expect that, after the

mandatory adoption of IFRS, only development expenditures from those R&D projects,

which are highly likely to be successful, are capitalised. However, as the application of these

conditions requires managers to exercise their judgment over proprietary and subjective

information, R&D capitalisation under IAS 38 still remains open to managerial discretion and

hence the reliability of such information can be questioned (Cazavan-Jeny, Jeanjean, & Joos,

2011; Dinh, Kang, & Schultze, 2015).

Because of the judgement involved, it follows that the potential discretionary treatment of

(4)

4

signalling effect conveying the future earnings’ power of the business associated with the

level of capitalisation. In these cases, ‘…investors perceive the capitalisation of R&D to be

related to successful R&D projects’ (Shah et al., 2013, p. 168). Second, consistent with

earnings management, a managerial opportunism manifested through a positive impact on

current earnings and possible earnings benchmark beating (Dinh et al., 2015), when costs are

capitalised and not expensed (Ahmed & Falk, 2006; Cazavan-Jeny & Jeanjean, 2006;

Cazavan-Jeny et al., 2011; Ciftci, 2010; Dinh et al., 2015). In these cases, managers provide a

noisy signal with regards to the future benefits associated with the R&D costs capitalised.

In this study, we examine the potential influence of corruption as a country characteristic

which may be associated with the accounting treatment of R&D, specifically development

costs, under IFRS. Corruption is commonly defined as the ‘abuse of entrusted power for

private gain’ (Transparency International, 2009, p. 7). Where corruption is prevalent,

business cheating and scandals are merely one manifestation of a much broader and more

insidious acceptance of corruption within society (Zuckerman, 2006, cited in Ashforth, Gioia,

Robinson, and Trevino (2008)). Effectively, in such settings, corruption is collectively

‘normalized (Ashforth & Anand, 2003) because it leads to a gradual erosion of moral agency

over time (Ashforth et al., 2008; Brief, Buttram, & Dukerich, 2001; Fleming &

Zyglidopoulos, 2008). Thus, as put forward by Ashforth and Anand (2003, p. 8), ‘once a

corrupt decision or act produces a positive outcome and is included in organizational

memory, it is likely to be used again in the future’ and this is not perceived as unacceptable.

Hence, in such environments, based on the rational expectation of a profit-maximising agent

(Kimbro, 2002), some managers use this non-market mechanism to improve their well-being

through exercising excess discretion (Hamir, 1999) to achieve income maximisation , over

(5)

5

Drawing upon this reasoning, prior empirical research has indeed shown that quality of

accounting is susceptible to the level of country-level corruption (Doupnik, 2008; Fan, Guan,

Li, & Yang, 2014; Han, Kang, Salter, & Yoo, 2008; Nabar & Boonlert-U-Thai, 2007; Picur,

2004). This is evident via a negative relationship between levels of corruption and

information transparency (DiRienzo et al., 2007), presence of big four auditors and perceived

levels of accounting and audit quality amongst business people (Malagueño, Albrecht, Ainge,

& Stephens, 2010), compliance with mandatory disclosures (e.g., about goodwill as examined

by Mazzi, Tsalavoutas, & Slack, 2017) and positive relationship between corruption and

earnings opacity1 (Picur, 2004; Riahi-Belkaoui, 2004).

On reflection of this evidence, our first hypothesis is that managerial discretion and

accounting choice associated with the amount of development costs capitalised, is positively

influenced by the level of country corruption. We argue that, in an attempt to project a

positive image for their firms’ current and future performance, managers in countries with

high levels of corruption, capitalise larger amounts of development costs, in comparison to

those countries with low levels of corruption. As explained earlier, capitalising and not

expensing development costs results in better current-year earnings (i.e., earnings

management effect) and raises expectations for future earnings due to high amounts of assets

capitalised (i.e., a noisy signalling effect). On that basis, our second hypothesis is that

development costs capitalised have a lower association with cumulative future earnings in the

long-run for firms in countries with higher corruption levels (i.e., those associated with

over-capitalisation). This is because the capitalised development costs would not deliver as high as

signalled future economic benefits.

1

(6)

6

Building on these two hypotheses, we next consider whether levels of firm

internationalisation moderate the influence of corruption on their capitalisation of

development costs and also the relationship between capitalised costs and their contribution

to future earnings. As firms become international through, for instance, exporting,

cross-listing or owning overseas subsidiaries, the influence of domestic corruption may diminish as

the firm becomes more exposed to international norms (Reid, 1983). Indeed, prior literature

shows that internationalisation positively influences management attitudes towards

stewardship and accountability (Murtha, Lenway, & Bagozzi, 1998; Segaro, Larimo, &

Jones, 2014), compared to more domestically-orientated firms (Nadkarni & Perez, 2007) and

serves to lessen the effect of domestic corruption (Sandholtz & Gray, 2003). Thus, our third

hypothesis is that the more international a firm is, the lower will be the influence of domestic

corruption on the magnitude of development costs capitalised. From this, our fourth

hypothesis follows. More specifically, the influence of domestic corruption on the

relationship between capitalised costs and future earnings will also be weaker for those firms

that are more international compared to more domestically-orientated firms where the

influence of local corruption will not be so diminished.

To test our hypotheses, we employ a sample of over 3,300 firm-year observations, across

20 countries, which were mandated to adopt IFRS in 2005. Our analyses cover the periods

2006 to 2015 and the findings show the following. First, after controlling for various firm and

other country characteristics, there is indeed a positive relation between country level

corruption and the amount of development costs capitalised. Further, we find that the higher

the levels of corruption, the lower the association of the capitalised development costs to

future profitability, compared to countries with lower levels of corruption. This finding is

(7)

7

management and a noisy signalling effect prevail, in relation to the managerial discretion on

the development costs capitalised. Additionally, in more international companies, the amount

of capitalised development costs is less influenced by domestic corruption compared to those

companies that are more domestically orientated. Finally, the contribution of capitalised

development costs to future profitability is negatively influenced by the level of domestic

corruption in less international firms.

By examining the potential effect of corruption on the levels of capitalised development

costs and their respective contribution to firm level earnings, we contribute to the literature as

follows. Firstly, in the only other IFRS study which examines the determinants of R&D

capitalisation to our knowledge (i.e. Dinh et al., 2015) neither corruption nor

internationalisation as country and firm level contextual factors respectively were considered.

Unlike our research which employs a global dataset, their study is restricted to Germany only,

and thus their findings are necessarily country specific and do not shed light on the potential

disparity of accounting and managerial choice associated with IAS 38 in a global context. By

drawing on corruption as a possible influence on accounting choice, this study provides one

hitherto unexamined aspect of that analysis. In doing so, this study responds to Shah et al.

(2013 p. 168) who call for ‘analysis regarding capitalising R&D expenditures [which] helps

managers to conduct earnings management’. Secondly, this study addresses the call by

(Houqe & Monem, 2016, p.3) who note that ‘literature linking corruption with accounting is

sparse’. Our analyses provide empirical findings in support of Ball (2006), Nobes (2006),

Weetman (2006), Zeff (2007) suggesting that country specific characteristics result in an

uneven application of IFRS worldwide, and arguably, with adverse effects to comparability.

The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2, discusses the relevant

(8)

8

and the methods employed. Section 4 presents and discusses the empirical findings. Section

5 illustrates additional tests and Section 6 concludes the paper by outlining the contributions

arising from this research. It also discusses limitations and avenues for further research.

2. Background, literature review and hypotheses development

2.1 R&D reporting under IFRS

Since 2005, all EU publicly traded firms need to report consolidated financial statements

under IFRS,2 with IAS 38 governing the accounting treatment of intangible assets. IAS 38

requires the capitalisation of development expenditures which meet a specific set of criteria.

In order to capitalise the development costs a company should assess: the technical

feasibility of the intangible asset; the intention to complete the asset and with the ability to

sell (or use) it; the availability of resources, technical or financial, to complete it; the ability

to reliably measure the expenditure and the ability to justify that the asset will generate

future economic benefits (paragraph 57).

Based upon meeting these conditions, a company must then capitalise development

expenditure; it is not a discretionary choice. However, in establishing whether all these

criteria are met, there is managerial judgement and hence effective discretion over the

capitalisation decision. As PricewaterhouseCoopers (2010) note, meeting the six conditions

“requires facts and some judgements” (p. 7, emphasis added). Thus, if the company decides

that one of the conditions is not met, then it must expense the relevant cost incurred.

Alternatively, and consistent with an earnings management and noisy signalling approach

(Ahmed & Falk, 2006, 2009; Cazavan-Jeny & Jeanjean, 2006; Cazavan-Jeny et al., 2011;

Ciftci, 2010; Dinh et al., 2015; Markarian et al., 2008; Prencipe, Markarian, & Pozza, 2008),

2

(9)

9

a company may judge that all of the conditions have been met and effectively over-capitalise

development costs.

2.2 The R&D capitalisation debate and academic evidence

The accounting treatment of R&D has been a controversial issue among standards setters,

financial statement preparers, users as well as academics. Under IFRS, certain development

costs can be capitalised (see above), with all other costs associated with R&D expensed. In

contrast to IAS 38, under US Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP)

(Statement of Financial Accounting Standards (hereafter SFAS) 2), all R&D costs are

expensed. However, Lev, Sarath, and Sougiannis (2005) argue that immediate expensing

leads to biases in earnings and mispriced stock prices and Amir, Guan, and Livne (2007)

conclude that uniform expensing of R&D costs is ‘overly conservative’ (p. 245). One of the

reasons behind this differential treatment are apparent concerns by Financial Accounting

Standards Board (FASB) regarding the uncertainty related to the future benefits expected by

the assets capitalised. Additionally, they are concerned that management may use their

discretion to capitalise R&D, resulting in a misrepresentation of R&D accounting data

(Davies & Wallington, 1999; Healy & Wahlen, 1999). This is why Ahmed and Falk (2006)

conclude that, standard setters, such as FASB, are concerned that ‘the cost of possible

misstatement to exceed the benefits of signalling’ (p. 234) (and mandate expensing all R&D

costs as a result).3

In summary, within this debate, two issues dominate. Firstly, development costs

effectively constitute investments which will result in future economic benefits and as a

result they should be capitalised (i.e., not expensed) to recognise their current value to the

3

(10)

10

business and to provide a signal for future earnings arising from successful development

expenditure (Lev, Nissim, & Thomas, 2008). On the other hand, capitalisation can effectively

be used as an earnings management vehicle. These inter-related effects are also highlighted

by Dinh et al. (2015) as follows: ‘R&D capitalisation can be exercised by managers to signal

private information on future economic benefits to the market. It can, however, also serve as

opportunistic earnings management’ (p. 1) (and see Ciftci, 2010).

Dealing with signalling, there is mixed evidence within the literature on the link between

capitalisation and future earnings. For instance, in relation to French companies in the

pre-IFRS period in which firms were permitted to capitalise development costs under certain

conditions, Cazavan-Jeny and Jeanjean (2006) find a significant and negative relationship of

capitalised development costs and share price. In line with our propositions, they suggest that

managers are more likely to take a more opportunistic approach to capitalisation, given the

country contextual factors (i.e., weak enforcement). Further, Cazavan-Jeny et al. (2011),

again in the same French context, find that decision to capitalise R&D expenditures is

generally associated with a negative or neutral impact on future performance, and hence

inconsistent with the proposition that managers capitalise R&D to convey information about

improved performance (i.e., genuine signaling effect).

In contrast and supportive of a capitalisation approach, Lev and Sougiannis (1996) in a US

based study (requiring full expensing of R&D) find that R&D expenses are associated with

future income. In an Australian context, where companies were permitted to capitalise

development costs under certain conditions under Australian GAAP, Ahmed and Falk (2006)

in their study for the period 1992 to 1999, find that, ‘R&D capitalised expenditure is

positively and significantly associated with the firm’s future earnings’ (p. 231). Thus, they

(11)

11

capitalising successful R&D investment or expensing unsuccessful R&D investment’ (p.

259). The market relevance of capitalised development cost, and the signalling of managerial

information relevant to future earnings, is also noted by Shah et al. (2013) using UK data

covering pre and post IFRS adoption, ‘that investors perceive the capitalisation of R&D to be

related to successful R&D projects’ (ibid, p. 168) (and see Oswald & Zarowin, 2007;

Tsoligkas & Tsalavoutas, 2011). Finally, in relation to software development (SD), in her US

study, Wolfe (2012) finds that the association between capitalised SD expenditures and

future cash flows is stronger than the association between reported R&D expense and future

cash flows for firms that capitalise.

In relation to the potential manipulation of capitalisation associated with earnings

management, whilst much of the prior literature is based upon national GAAP rather than

IAS, consistent findings have been reported. Cazavan-Jeny et al. (2011) contend that

managers may capitalise development costs to meet or beat earnings thresholds/targets or to

avoid reporting losses. In their Italian study, based on the pre-IFRS period (where similar to

France and Australia noted earlier) companies were permitted to capitalise development

costs under certain conditions, Markarian et al. (2008) conclude on the motivations for

capitalisation as forming part of earnings management for earnings smoothing. Finally, Dinh

et al. (2015), in their study on Germany, which covers companies reporting under IFRS,

found that ‘pressure to beat past year’s earnings and analysts’ forecast of earnings increases

the probability of a firm capitalising R&D in the current period. This evidence is in line with

the notion of firms opportunistically managing earnings via R&D capitalisation’ (p. 3). They

contend that both the decision to capitalise and how much to capitalise are strongly and

(12)

12

earnings management counteracts the signaling value of capitalisation, a finding consistent

with the noted regulatory concerns in the US.

2.3 Hypotheses development

Prior empirical research has, almost universally, found that corruption has an adverse impact

on business activity due to a lack of transparency and the misallocation and inefficient use of

resources. For example, it is widely found to result in lower levels of foreign direct

investment and levels of economic growth (Bryant & Javalgi, 2016; Voyer & Beamish,

2004). Additionally, companies in countries with high levels of corruption tend to have

lower levels of corporate social performance disclosures (Baldini, Dal Maso, Liberatore,

Mazzi, & Terzani, 2016; Ioannou & Serafeim, 2012). Finally, earlier research, has shown a

negative relationship between low levels of corruption and information transparency in

general (DiRienzo et al., 2007; Kimbro, 2002).

In a more accounting specific context, Malagueño et al. (2010) examine accounting and

auditing quality and the perceived level of corruption across 57 countries. They find that

both accounting and auditing quality are negatively related to the level of perceived

corruption. Fan et al. (2014) highlight the link of earnings opacity and corruption in China,

whereby managers distort accounting information to cover their expropriation of interests

from common investors. Similarly, Picur (2004) and Riahi-Belkaoui (2004), in their

multi-country studies, find significant and positive relationships between the level of corruption

and the level of earnings opacity, indicative of earnings opacity being susceptible to

corruption. Riahi-Belkaoui (2004, p. 73) asserts that ‘the variations in earnings opacity

internationally suggest the presence of local factors that act as major determinants of its level

(13)

13

determinant of the level of earnings opacity’. Overall, this literature suggests that in more

corrupt environments managers are more likely to distort earnings, reflecting managerial

opportunism.

From this, and in line with the prior literature which suggests that managers take an

opportunistic approach to capitalisation of development costs (Cazavan-Jeny & Jeanjean,

2006; Cazavan-Jeny et al., 2011; Dinh et al., 2015; Markarian et al., 2008), it follows that

managers in a more corrupt environment would capitalise higher amounts of development

costs. Hence, we test the following hypothesis:

H1: There is a positive relation between country level corruption and the amount of development costs capitalised.

Assuming that H1 holds, beyond that capitalising and not expensing development costs

would result in better current-year earnings, managers falsely signal their private information

in relation to the future economic benefits associated with the capitalised development costs.

Thus, one would expect that the contribution of development costs capitalised and

cumulative future earnings in the long-run would not be as high for firms in countries with

higher corruption levels. This is because the capitalised development costs would not deliver

as high as signalled future economic benefits. Hence, we test the following hypothesis:

H2. The higher the corruption in a country, the lower the association of the capitalised development costs to future profitability.

We are primarily interested in the overall effect of corruption on capitalisation of

development costs. Thus, H1 & H2 are our main hypotheses. However, if it is the case that

country level corruption influences capitalisation of development costs and the resulting

contribution to future earnings, then the effect of domestic corruption may be affected by the

extent to which a particular firm is exposed to foreign norms and behaviours. Thus, we are

(14)

14

should diminish as firms become more exposed to foreign economic environments.

Following on from this, in more international firms the contribution of the capitalised

development costs to future profitability will not be as reduced due to domestic corruption

influences compared to those less international firms. Effectively, we examine if the relation

between corruption and capitalisation of development costs, as well as their contribution to

future earnings, is moderated by the degree of internationalisation measured at the firm level.

The rationale of these additional hypotheses is as follows.

One of the strategic choices that firms undertake is the internationalisation of their

business activity. Internationalisation can be defined as ‘the process of increasing

involvement in international operations’ (Welch & Luostarinen, 1988, p. 84). Drawing on the

strategic management and international business literature, Reid (1983) highlights the

importance of export market characteristics, such as economic and social norms, becoming

recognised and part of a firm’s decision-making processes. As such, firms will adapt and

adopt an increasingly market centred, as opposed to domestic, approach to international

business. Johanson and Vahlne (1990) process model of internationalisation further

highlights the need for firms to make adaptations in their ways of performing business to

signal their credibility to international partners and networks (Ford, 1979; Turnbull & Valla,

2013). Moreover, as part of the internationalisation process, Murtha et al. (1998) argue that

managerial thinking and attitudes towards issues such as accountability and global values are

critical for strategic change. In line with this, Segaro et al. (2014), in their research

examining SME behaviour, argue that through the process of internationalisation,

stewardship and the long-term orientation of the firm become more embedded in managerial

thinking and attitudes. The resource diversity of internationalisation, compared to the

(15)

15

environment (Nadkarni & Perez, 2007; O'Grady & Lane, 1996). From this, it derives that the

more international the firm is the more long term-orientation and stronger elements of

stewardship it has (Murtha et al., 1998; Segaro et al., 2014).

With regard to corruption in particular, Sandholtz and Gray (2003) assert that as

international trade augments international norms, the effect of corruption is reduced on those

involved with trade, consistent with a ‘significant inverse relationship between international

trade and corruption levels’ (p. 765). From the foregoing, it follows that the more

international a firm becomes, compared to those more domestic firms, the less it will be

influenced by local corruption (c.f., Ades & Di Tella, 1999).

These arguments are also informed by the evidence in the accounting literature which

provide wider evidence that the impact of country-level corruption at a firm-level is reduced

through internationalisation. For example, Dauth, Pronobis, and Schmid (2017, p. 71)

provide evidence that, ‘top management internationalisation mitigates the level of managerial

discretion in financial reporting’. Additionally, Hope, Kang, Thomas, and Yoo (2008) argue

that if a domestic firm derives most of its revenues from overseas operations, or if the firm is

cross-listed, then the firm ‘is less likely affected by domestic norms – such as the extent of

secrecy in the country’ (p.361) than other, less internationally-oriented firms.4 They find that

firms in secretive environments are more likely to employ a non-Big 4 auditor with negative

implications for the quality of financial statements. Thus, they suggest that ‘...multinational

firms are less affected by home country cultural norms than are domestic firms’ (p. 371).

In an earnings management context in particular, Lang, Lins, and Miller (2003) and Lang,

Raedy, and Yetman (2003) employ cross-listing as a measure of internationalisation and find

4

(16)

16

that cross-listed firms have better, more transparent, information environments and would

appear to be less aggressive in terms of earnings management. Moreover, In fact,

‘multinationals tend to carry out less income-increasing earnings management than domestic

firms’ (Prencipe, 2012: 693). This is particularly relevant to our context given that

capitalisation of development costs results in income increasing earnings management as

discussed earlier.

From the foregoing, we would argue that companies with an international focus are less

driven by local factors due to internationalisation, and as a result, the influence of domestic

corruption would diminish. In our context, the short-term opportunism by over-capitalising

development costs that is influenced by local norms of corrupt behaviour would be less

pronounced. Thus, we hypothesise that the effect of corruption on the amount of capitalised

development costs would be lower for those companies that are more international.

H3. The amount of capitalised development costs will be more influenced by domestic corruption in firms with lower levels of internationalisation.

From this and on reflection of H2, it derives that the expected positive effect of capitalised

development costs to future earnings is moderated by the extent of domestic corruption when

the company is less international. Thus, we also test the following hypothesis:

(17)

17 3. Research design

3.1 Sample selection process

The data selection starts by focusing on the countries that adopted IFRS on a mandatory basis

in 2005, as reported in Daske, Hail, Leuz, and Verdi (2008).5 We then retain in our sample all

companies reporting either an R&D asset or an R&D expense in the period between 2006 and

2010. We exclude the first year of IFRS adoption (i.e., for the reporting period 2005) to

reduce the potential for any misreporting due to low familiarity with IFRS at the time. We

obtain data from Worldscope/Datastream and include all companies in the research lists of

dead and active firms constructed by Datastream for each country in our sample. To avoid

double counting, firms that are cross-listed in more than one market are included in our

sample once, based only on the country of primary listing. In addition, we eliminate

instruments which are not classified as equity. The sample period ends in 2010 because we

require five years of data subsequent to that year (i.e., 2011-2015) to measure future

performance. Subsequently, we eliminate companies belonging to the Oil and Gas industry

due to extraction costs, which could be classified as development costs. Given that we focus

on firms which adopted IFRS, we eliminate all those companies which do not report under

IFRS for the whole of the sample period i.e., they switched from IFRS to other GAAP at

some point in the sample period.6 Following García Lara, García Osma, and Mora (2005), we

also exclude firms with accounting periods of more than 380 or less than 350 days and firm

year observations with insufficient data. In addition, we exclude observations where the

5

It is noted that Daske et al. (2008) include Switzerland and Venezuela but they are excluded from our sample. Switzerland did not implement IFRS at that time; it gave companies the option to adopt IFRS or US GAAP instead. Venezuala was excluded due to it being an economy with hyper-inflation and as such only fully adopted IFRSs in 2008 with some modifications for inflation.

6We rely on Worldscope item ‘accounting standards followed’

(18)

18

Inverted Mills ratio could not be estimated7 (see below). This process results in our sample

consisting of 3,383 firm year observations corresponding to 1,122 firms, across 20 countries.

We classify firm year observations as a capitaliser if a company capitalises R&D during the

year, otherwise we consider the company as an expenser. In total, we have 1,576 capitalisers

and 1,807 expensers. Panel A of Table 1 summarises the data selection process and shows the

breakdown between capitalisers and expensers.

Panels B and C of Table 1 show the sample distribution by industry classification using

ICB Super Sector (ICB Level 2) and country, respectively. We observe a good distribution of

our sample firms across industries, with most of the firms being from the Industrials (1,042),

Technology (606), Consumer Goods (592) Health Care (495) and Basic Materials (362)

industry sectors. Moreover, there is also a good distribution of the sample observations across

countries (e.g., UK (814), Germany (565), France (397), Australia (270), Sweden (259),

Finland (218), Italy (178)).8

TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE

3.2 Corruption as a determinant of development costs capitalised (H1 & H3)

We first test H1 (i.e., whether corruption affects positively the amount of R&D capitalised),

by estimating the following zero (i.e., left) sensored Tobit model:

RDCAP=b0 + b1Corruption + b2∑Controls + Industry fixed effects + Year fixed effects +ε(1)

where, RDCap is the amount of R&D capitalised during the year; Corruption is the measure

of country level corruption. Our measure of corruption is based on the Corruption Perception

Index (CPI) calculated from Transparency International (TI) and has been extensively used

7

This happens due to perfect failure of the probit model; some industries have no variation in CAP (the 0-1 dummy variable) and we cannot estimate the probit model.

8

(19)

19

by prior literature as a proxy for corruption in a country (e.g. DeBacker, Heim, & Tran, 2015;

Liu, 2016; Mazzi et al., 2017).9 CPI is calculated annually and scores countries based on the

perceived level of corruption in the public sector. TI records countries which are less corrupt

as top scorers. Therefore, a higher CPI rank indicates a less corrupt country and vice versa.

To assist the interpretation of our findings, we construct Corruption as the difference between

the highest possible CPI score (i.e., 10) minus each country’s corruption level. Thus, the

higher the difference the more corrupt a country in our sample and, as a result, a higher

(lower) value of Corruption would indicate higher (lower) level of corruption. In line with

H1, we expect the coefficient b1 to be positive indicating that firms in more corrupt countries

capitalise higher amounts of development costs.

To avoid the Corruption measure capturing the underlying effect of other country level

factors which could also have an influence on managerial accounting choice, country level

controls include the following: RDdivergence is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if

capitalisation of development or research costs was permitted or required prior to 2005 and 0

if no such capitalisation was permitted. CivCom is a dummy variable that takes the value of 0

if the country is characterised with common law and 1 if with civil law. InvProtection is a

measure of investor protection calculated as principal component analysis of disclosure,

liability standards, and anti-director rights (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Shleifer, 2008).

AudEnf is an index capturing the degree of accounting enforcement activity in each country

measured in 2008. MrktDev is the market capitalisation of listed companies as a % of GDP

9

(20)

20

and AntiselfDeal is the Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (2008) anti

self-dealing index.

In addition, we include a battery of firm level control variables which prior (primarily

non-IFRS) literature shows to affect the capitalisation of R&D as a function of a firm’s life cycle

and whether the firm meets the conditions for capitalisation (Aboody & Lev, 1998;

Cazavan-Jeny et al., 2011; Dinh et al., 2015; Markarian et al., 2008; Oswald, 2008; Oswald &

Zarowin, 2007), namely: book to market ratio (BM), as a measure of risk and growth;

RDValue which is a proxy for the success of a firm’s R&D expenditure; R&D intensity

(RDInt) which determines whether the magnitude of R&D expenditure affects the decision to

capitalise R&D; the natural logarithm of market value of the company (Size); beta (Beta) as a

proxy for risk because riskier firms are more likely to engage in basic research which is

expensed than less risky firms (Aboody & Lev, 1998); and finally total debt to book value of

equity (Leverage), as a proxy for financial health. Additionally, we include the ratio of

foreign sales to total sales (IntSalesPerc) to capture whether internationalisation influences

the level of capitalisation through synergies with international partners.

We also create dummy variables which capture the likelihood of a company managing

earnings in an attempt to achieve certain earnings targets. Following Dinh et al. (2015), we

introduce PastBeat which takes the value of 1 if prior year’s earnings is greater that this

year’s earnings, assuming full expensing and smaller than this year’s earnings assuming full

capitalisation, and 0 otherwise. In addition, we include a similar dummy variable for the zero

earnings threshold (ZeroBeat). Specifically, this takes the value of 1 if the zero earnings

threshold is greater that this year’s earnings assuming full expensing and smaller than this

year’s earnings assuming full capitalisation, and 0 otherwise. We also combine the latter two

(21)

21

Subsequently for testing H3, we estimate the same regression across the sub-samples of

low and high internationalisation. Internationalisation is measured by the ratio of foreign

sales to total sales (Dauth et al., 2017; Glaum, Baetge, Grothe, & Oberdörster, 2013; Hamori

& Koyuncu, 2011). Based upon this measure, we then calculate the median value which

determines the two sub-samples of high and low international firms respectively. We then

compare the size, and the significance of any difference, of the coefficients of the variable

Corruption to infer the differential influence of domestic corruption on the amounts

capitalised across the two sub-samples.

3.2 Capitalised development costs, corruption, and future performance (H2 & H4)

To examine the influence of corruption on the relationship between capitalised development

costs and future profits we employ a regression model which is similar to Curtis, McVay, and

Toynbee (2014) and is as follows:

NI= a0, + b1RDCap + b2RDExp+ b3∑Controls + Industry fixed effects + Year fixed effects + ε (2)

where, NI is one measure of future earnings10 being the sum of future earnings measured

from year t+1 to year t+5 scaled by the market value of equity. Earnings are defined as

operating income plus the R&D expense and depreciation and amortisation.11 As an

alternative, we also employ NI2 which isthe sum of future earnings defined as the net profit

before extraordinary items measured from t+1 to t+5 scaled by the market value of equity.

Earnings are defined as income before extraordinary items, R&D expenditure, depreciation

and amortisation; RDCap is the amount of R&D capitalised during the year; and RDExp is

the amount of R&D expensed during the year. We also include an indicator variable equal to

10

We use earnings because earnings is deemed as a more direct measure of the benefits associated with R&D (Lev & Sougiannis, 1996).

11

(22)

22

1 if the company capitalises development costs during the year (CAP). Following Kothari,

Laguerre, and Leone (2002), Amir et al. (2007)12 and Curtis et al. (2014) controls include

capital expenditure (Capex), Leverage and Size (both as defined in the previous regression

model). Moreover, we include the ratio of foreign sales to total sales (IntSalesPerc) to capture

whether internationalisation influences future firm profitability through greater market

access. In addition, we include the following country controls: MrktDev and Enforcement

(again, both as defined in the previous regression model). A positive coefficient of b1 will

indicate that the capitalised amount of R&D is associated with future economic benefits

which would be in line with the asset recognition criteria in IAS 38. Considering that this is

the first study to analyse the consequences of R&D to future profits under IFRS, we do not

have an ex-ante prediction for the coefficient of R&D expense.

Similarly to Oswald and Zarowin (2007) and Dinh et al. (2015), we control for the

endogenous decision to capitalise R&D using the two-stage approach of Heckman (1979) and

use the Inverse Mills Ratio (IMR) retrieved from estimating a probit model. The results of

these estimations are presented in Appendix I.

To test H2 and subsequently H4, we introduce our measure of corruption in model (2)

both as a main effect as well as an interaction term with the R&D asset (RDCap) and R&D

expense (RDExp), as follows:

NI= a0, + b1RDCap + b2RDCap*Corruption + b3RDExp+ b4RDExp*Corruption

+ b5Corruption + b6∑Controls + Industry fixed effects + Year fixed effects + ε

(3)

The coefficient b1 captures the relation between future earnings and R&D asset, while the

coefficient b2 captures the incremental effect of corruption on this relation. Consistent with

12

(23)

23

H2, we expect the coefficient b2 to be negative and b1 to be positive indicating that the

capitalised amount of R&D is associated with less future economic benefits in more corrupt

countries. We do not have an ex-ante prediction for b3 and b4.

In estimating all regressions (equations 1 and 2), we add industry dummy variables based

on the ICB Level 2 industry classification. Further, we also control for cross-sectional and

time series correlation by adding year fixed effects and clustering by firm. We winsorise all

the continuous variables at the 1 percent level on both tails of the distribution. We report all

the variables employed in our models together with their source in Appendix II.

Finally, for testing H4, we estimate the same regression across the sub-samples of low and

high internationalisation as described earlier. We then compare the size of the coefficients,

and the significance of any difference, of the variable RDCap*Corruption to infer the

differential influence of domestic corruption on the contribution of the capitalised

development costs to future profitability across the two sub-samples.

4. Results

4.1 Descriptive statistics

Table 2 shows descriptive statistics for corruption (CPI), market development (MrktDev) and

level of enforcement (Enforcement) in the countries included in our sample. This reveals a

range of values between all of the countries for corruption and in relation to the other country

relevant variables. For example, whilst focusing on countries with relatively large number of

observations in the sample, Australia, Sweden, Denmark and Finland (represented by 857

observations) have the lowest levels of corruption (ranging from 0.640 to 1.323). At the other

extreme, Italy, South Africa, Greece, Poland and Spain have highest levels of corruption

(24)

24

same sets of countries, values of enforcement range from 32 to 52 for those countries with

low corruption levels and between 26 to 46 for the countries with higher levels of corruption

depicting a lower level of enforcement. Similar variations exist in relation to market

development.

TABLE 2 ABOUT HERE

Panel A of Table 3 shows descriptive statistics for all the variables used in our models for the

full sample. These reveal, inter alia, that 46.6% of firm-year observations in our sample

capitalise some development costs while the remaining totally expense them in the income

statement. While the capitalised development costs (RDCap) accounts for 1.3% of market

value on average, the expensed R&D (RDExp) is around 5.5% of MV. The average firm-year

observation in our sample has also a book value to market value of equity (BM) of 0.68,

shows a material R&D intensity (RDInt) of 6.1%, and has a a Leverage ratio of around

65.7%.

TABLE 3 ABOUT HERE

Panel B of Table 3 reports descriptive statistics for the dependent and independent variables

used in the multivariate analyses for the two sub-samples of Expensers and Capitalisers. The

former has a mean (median) NIof 1.087 (0.911), while the latter exhibit a mean (median)

future earnings of 1.35 (1.02). T-test (Mann-Whitney test) indicates that the mean (median)

NI for Capitalisers is significantly higher (p<0.01) than the mean (median) for Expensers.

The statistics are similar for NI2. The mean (median) R&D expense (RDExp) for the

subsample of Expensers is 0.052 (0.022), while the mean RDExp for Capitalisers is 0.059

(0.020). T-test (Mann-Whitney test) shows that there is a strong statistically significant

difference across the two sub-samples. This may not be surprising given that a large number

(25)

25

The subsample of Capitalisers shows an average (median) RDInt of 0.059 (0.021), while the

mean (median) of the corresponding amount for Expensers is 0.063 (0.030) being

significantly smaller based on a Mann-Whitney test (p<0.01). These descriptive statistics

indicate that, as expected, companies that capitalise some or all of the development costs are

firms that are more R&D intensive and have significantly higher future profitability.

Additionally, and as shown in prior literature (e.g. Dinh et al., 2015; Oswald, 2008), T-test

and Mann-Whitney test indicate that Capitalisers are smaller (mean Size = 13.01 for

Expensers vs. mean Size = 12.614 for Capitalisers; p<0.01), riskier (mean Beta = 0.929 for

Expensers vs. mean Beta = 0.980 for Capitalisers; p<0.05) and more levered (mean Leverage

= 0.591 for Expensers vs. mean Leverage = 0.733 for Capitalisers; p<0.01).

4.2 Univariate analysis

We present Pearson correlation coefficients between all variables in Table 4. The correlations

between the key variables of interest (i.e., RDCAP, Corruption, NI and NI2) and other

variables indicate the following. As hypothesized, the amount capitalised is positively and

significantly correlated with Corruption (0.072; p<0.01). Additionally, as expected from

evidence in prior literature, the amount capitalised is also positively and significantly

correlated with future earnings (NI and NI2 exhibit a positive correlation at 1% level) but also

earnings benchmark beating (PastBeat, ZeroBeat and BenchBeat, all exhibit a positive

correlation at 1% level), BM (i.e., growth) (0.257; p<0.01), RDInt (0.236; p<0.01), Leverage

(0.046, p<0.01), and Enforcement (0.094; p<0.01).

Although these results depict a picture in line with our first hypothesis, they are unable to

(26)

26

cannot bring into light the moderating effect of corruption and internationalisation. Thus,

results are further explored with multivariate analyses in the following section.

TABLE 4 ABOUT HERE

4.3 Multivariate analysis

Table 5 reports results for multivariate analysis testing the effect of corruption on the

magnitude of development costs capitalised. Models 1, 3 and 5 differ from 2, 4 and 6

respectively only for the measures used to proxy earnings benchmark beating.

Focusing on the full sample, the results support H1: firms in countries with higher levels

of corruption capitalise higher amounts of development costs. In fact, the coefficient for

Corruption is positive as expected and statistically significant across both models 1 and 2

(always at the 1% level). Confirming univariate analysis, our results also indicate that the

amount of capitalised development costs is positively influenced by R&D intensity (RDInt),

growth (BM), internationalisation (IntSalesPerc) and leverage (Leverage). In addition, we

report that Size negatively affects the amount of development costs capitalised. Further, our

multivariate analysis confirms that amount of development costs capitalised is significantly

affected by earnings management, as the coefficients for the measures derived from Dinh et

al. (2015) are always positive and statistically significant.

Models 3 to 6 report the multivariate analyses testing H3. We report that both for firms

with low and high international exposure, Corruption is positively and significantly

associated with the amount of development costs capitalised. However, tests comparing the

size of the coefficients of the variable Corruption across all models indicate that these are

significantly higher for the sub-sample of firms with lower levels of internationalisation.

(27)

27

TABLE 5 ABOUT HERE

Table 6 reports results for multivariate analysis testing the moderating role of corruption in

the relationship between R&D and future earnings for the full sample but also across the

sub-samples of firms with lower and higher levels of internationalisation. These analyses test

hypotheses H2 and H4. As previously, Models 7, 9 and 11 differ from 8, 10 and 12

respectively only for the measures used to proxy earnings benchmark beating.

These multivariate analyses, firstly, confirm the rationale that capitalised development

costs are mirrored in future economic benefits as the coefficient for RDCap is positive and

statistically significant across all model specifications. Moreover, this analysis illustrates the

moderating role of corruption in the relationship between R&D and future earnings,

supporting H2. In both models 7 and 8 the coefficient for the interaction between RDCap and

Corruption is negative (statistically significant at the 5% level) suggesting that the

association between capitalised development costs and future earnings is lower in more

corrupt countries. Additionally, expensed R&D (RDExp) is also positively correlated with

future earnings (again at the 1% level). The latter suggests that there is still an element in the

amounts expensed that contributes to future earnings.

TABLE 6 ABOUT HERE

Secondly, the results across the sub-samples of firms with higher and lower levels of

internationalisation provide a clearer picture of the role of domestic corruption. The tests

across Models 9 and 12 reveal that the contribution of capitalised development costs to

future earnings when corruption is higher is present only for the sub-sample of firms with

lower levels of internationalisation. These results are in support of H4.

The combined results of these tests and those presented in Table 5 indicate the following.

(28)

28

expected future earnings is not as high as expected when domestic corruption is high. This

finding is associated with the sub-sample of firms with low internationalisation. For firms

with high internationalisation, domestic corruption does not impair the benefit from the

amounts capitalised, suggesting that these amounts genuinely represent future economic

benefits which are mirrored in companies’ future profitability. In fact, the positive influences

of the expensed amounts revealed for the full sample is driven only by this sub-sample of

firms.

4.4 Discussion of findings

On reflection of our hypotheses and informed by prior literature, the following inferences can

be drawn from the results presented. Whilst the level of development cost capitalisation is

positively associated with a number of firm-level characteristics, for instance, R&D intensity,

growth and leverage it is also influenced by corruption as a country characteristic. More

specifically, we show a strong significant association between country corruption and levels

of development cost capitalisation (H1) and, further in such cases, the lower the contribution

of the capitalised development costs to future earnings (H2).

Such findings are broadly consistent with that strand of the accounting literature prior to

the mandatory of IFRS that finds that accounting choices, such as capitalisation, are

associated with earnings management, for instance to avoid reporting a loss, to achieve

earnings smoothing or benchmark beating (Cazavan-Jeny & Jeanjean, 2006; Cazavan-Jeny et

al., 2011; Dinh et al., 2015; Markarian et al., 2008). For example, Cazavan-Jeny et al. (2011,

p. 146) contend that their ‘...results are therefore consistent with managers potentially

capitalising R&D expenditures to achieve certain financial reporting objectives’. Moreover,

(29)

29

Han et al., 2008; Nabar & Boonlert-U-Thai, 2007) conducive to earnings management (Fan et

al., 2014; Picur, 2004; Riahi-Belkaoui, 2004) such as the aggressive use of capitalisation. It is

due to concerns of such accounting, and the potential manipulation of earnings, that US

GAAP requires all R&D costs to be expensed (SFAS 2).

Inherent with capitalisation is the signalling effect, based upon hitherto proprietary

information, regarding the strength of future earnings. Overall, the literature is more mixed as

to the affect of capitalised costs on future earnings. As Ahmed and Falk (2006) summarise,

‘when a firm capitalises expenditure and reports the amount as an asset in its financial

statements, it signals good news. The capitalisation decision suggests that, in the reporting

entity’s judgment, the capitalised expenditure is expected to yield benefits to the

entity…likely to be realized in the foreseeable future’ (p. 232) (see Shah et al., 2013; Wolfe,

2012). However this is in contrast to the more negative findings regarding the relationship

between capitalisation and future earnings (for instance Cazavan-Jeny and Jeanjean (2006)

(for instance Cazavan-Jeny & Jeanjean, 2006). Our findings reveal a consistency of

over-capitalisation, associated with high levels of corruption, and its impaired ability to generate

stronger future earnings, effectively sending noisy or misleading signals regarding future

earnings.

Furthermore, as a firm becomes more international, levels of home country risk factors,

such as that associated with high corrupt environments, may diminish as the firm becomes

more exposed to international norms and levels of scrutiny reducing potential managerial

discretion in accounting choice (Sandholtz & Gray, 2003) Our findings in relation to H3

confirm that as a firm becomes more international, the influence of home country corruption

on capitalisation is mitigated. Such a finding is consistent with the literature on domestic and

(30)

30

p. 693) finds that ‘multinationals tend to carry out less income-increasing earnings

management than domestic firms’. Further, Lang, Lins, et al. (2003) and Lang, Raedy, et al.

(2003) find that international firms, through cross-listing, are more transparent, and less

aggressive in accounting choices, than domestic firms. It follows from H3, and the preceding

findings of H1 and H2, that the influence of home country corruption on the contribution of

capitalised costs to future earnings is mitigated with levels of internationalisation.

These findings, examining corruption as a country factor influencing accounting choice

provide new insights into the accounting literature, where such research is sparse (Houqe &

Monem, 2016) despite the recognized link between corruption and earnings opacity. Further,

whilst Dinh et al. (2015)examined R&D capitalisation, that study did not shed any light on

the determinants of capitalisation from an international context, nor did it consider the

potential and (now revealed) significant influence of corruption.

5. Sensitivity analyses13

5.1 Corruption and excessive development costs capitalisation levels.

The findings presented earlier suggest that, in environments where corruption levels are

high, companies engage with excessive and not accurate capitalisation of development costs.

However, our research design does not allow us to distinguish whether companies capitalise

more than they would be expected to capitalise given the industry in which they operate. To

address this concern and for shedding more light on our main findings, we proceed as

follows.

We draw on the earnings management via discretionary accruals literature and in the spirit

of Jones (1991), Boynton, Dobbins, and Plesko (1992) and DeFond and Jiambalvo (1994) ,

13

(31)

31

we perform additional analyses intended to estimate the unexpected amount of R&D

capitalised. Subsequently, we test its association with the country-level of corruption, while

controlling for all other country factors. More specifically, first, we estimate a zero (i.e., left)

censored Tobit model as in equation 1. We estimate this for every single industry-year in our

sample and we include firm-level controls only. Then, we predict the fitted values and

residuals, proxying for the expected and unexpected amount of R&D capitalised in a given

cluster respectively.14

These estimations allow us evaluate the country level influences on the expected and

unexpected amounts. We do so by estimating equation 1, while also including the country

controls, twice: once by replacing the amount of R&D capitalised with the expected and

once by replacing it with the unexpected amount. The results from these tests show that the

country level of corruption is significantly and positively associated with the unexpected part

of R&D capitalised only. This confirms the trend we identify in our main analyses that the

higher the domestic corruption the higher the amounts capitalised. Moreover, we replicate

these analyses across the two sub-samples of high and low internationalisation and we find

that our main results are also robust. The impact of corruption on the unexpected amount of

R&D capitalised is less prominent for more international firms.

5.2 Alternative measures of corruption and internationalisation.

One concern with our results is that the measure of corruption may not capture country

corruption in an efficient way. To alleviate this concern, we repeat all our tests by using two

alternative measures of corruption. More specifically, we examine whether our results hold

when we measure corruption, first, based on Bribery and Corruption provided by the

14

(32)

32

International Institute for Management Development (IMD) Yearbooks and, second, when

we substitute it with the cultural value of Secrecy. For both cases, the results remain

qualitatively similar to those presented earlier.

Additionally, we consider an alternative specification to capture firm level

internationalisation, that of analysts following. The results of these additional tests remain

qualitatively similar to those presented earlier.

5.3 Consideration of number of observations and country level economic development

For the analyses presented in Table 6 with regard to H2 and H4, one could argue that

economic growth may be already low in corrupt countries. Thus, it could be argued that it is

not surprising that the R&D capitalised would then produce lower levels of future profit

flows. To account for this, we estimate country GDP growth for the entire five year periods

which we use to measure cumulative future earnings. These tests indeed reveal that five-year

change in GDP is positively and significantly associated with firm-level future profitability.

The results with regard to the hypotheses tested remain same as those presented earlier.

Finally, we replicate our analysis by excluding countries with less than 50 firm-year

observations. Following this approach, we drop firms from Hong Kong, Ireland, Philippines,

Portugal, and Singapore. Our main results are robust to this additional test, showing that less

represented countries do not influence our inferences.

6. Conclusions

The accounting treatment of R&D has been a controversial issue among standards setters,

financial statement preparers and users as well as academics. Advocates for capitalising

(33)

33

economic benefits and as a result they should be capitalised (e.g. Lev & Sougiannis, 1996).

In line with this premise, IFRS prescribe that, when certain criteria are met, including

demonstration of future economic benefits, development costs only must be capitalised.

Arguably, by imposing the restrictive conditions in IAS 38 reduces the managerial

opportunism that may result from discretion involved in R&D capitalisation (Markarian et

al., 2008; Matolcsy & Wyatt, 2006) and one would expect that only development

expenditures from those R&D projects, which are highly likely to be successful, are

capitalised. As a consequence, managers can signal their private information about the

expected success of R&D ventures and the related future benefits to the market (Abrahams

& Sidhu, 1998; Oswald & Zarowin, 2007; Ritter & Wells, 2006). Indeed, capitalising R&D

has been found to be informative (Ahmed & Falk, 2006; Oswald & Zarowin, 2007).

However, since the application of the conditions in IAS 38 requires managers to make

judgment, R&D capitalisation under IAS 38 remains subject to managerial discretion and

possible earnings management. Such premise finds support in academic research which

reports that the discretion involved in R&D capitalisation can be used for opportunistic

earnings management, resulting in capitalisation being uninformative (Cazavan-Jeny &

Jeanjean, 2006; Markarian et al., 2008; Prencipe et al., 2008). This is why reliability of such

information can be easily questioned (c.f., Kothari et al., 2002) and in part giving rise to this

research.

However, in this study, we consider prior accounting literature which highlights the

importance of country corruption on accounting choices and explore the potential effect on

corruption on R&D reporting in particular, for which evidence is absent. More specifically,

we employ a large sample of listed firms across the world and, first, we examine the role of

(34)

34

and not expensing development costs would suggest better earnings figures in the current

year. Second, assuming that the first hypothesis holds, one would expect that cumulative

future earnings in the long-run would not be as high for firms in countries with higher

corruption levels. This is because the capitalised development costs would not deliver as

high as signalled future economic benefits. This would lead to lower earnings for these firms

compared to those in countries with lower corruption levels which capitalise based on

meeting IAS 38 criteria instead. Our empirical findings support both hypotheses. Finally, we

find that the effect of corruption as an influential factor for the capitalisation of higher

amounts of development costs, which then lead to lower future profitability, is more

pronounced in companies of lower international exposure. These analyses illustrate that, in

more corrupt countries, managers potentially send false signals to financial statements users

by being more likely to capitalise higher amounts of development costs, which do not bring

future economic benefits. Instead, companies with a more international exposure are less

influenced by the levels of domestic corruption and thus local environment. From this, such

internationally oriented companies capitalise more appropriately and hence better signal the

Gambar

Table 1 – Sample selection process and sample summary statistics
Table 2 – Country descriptive statistics
Table 3 – Descriptive statistics
Table 4 – Pearson’s correlation coefficients
+3

Referensi

Dokumen terkait

Muatan Kurikulum SMA Negeri 1 Payung Sekaki meliputi sejumlah mata pelajaran yang keluasan dan kedalamannya sesuai dengan Standar Kompetensi dan Kompetensi Dasar

judul ” Pengaruh Prestasi Belajar dan Latar Belakang Keluarga Terhadap Motivasi Berwirausaha pada Mahasiswa DPTA UPI Bandung ”. Identifikasi dan Masalah

Berilah tanda check list ( √) pada salah satu dari kolom yang tersedia di samping pertanyaan untuk menunjukkan jawaban yang anda pilih.. STP : Sangat tidak puas TP :

Skripsi ini telah diuji dan dinyatakan sah oleh Panitia Ujian Tingkat Sarjana (S1) Fakultas Keguruan dan Ilmu Pendidikan Universitas Muhammadiyah Surabaya sebagai salah satu

laut pada tekanan yang lebih rendah dengan suplai energi panas yang lebih sedikit3. dibanding dengan teknik

Isi dari Konferensi Meja Bundar: (1) Belanda mengakui kedaulatan Republik Indonesia Serikat (RIS) sebagai sebuah negara yang merdeka, (2) Status Provinsi Irian

Berdasarkan uraian tersebut, maka peneliti mencoba untuk melakukan penelitian yang bertujuan untuk menjelaskan pengaruh variabel konflik kerja (X 1 ) dan stres kerja (X 2 )

In the case of Text 4, it had material process and relational process as the predominant processes, in which it made this text successfully follow the linguistic features